Probably not.
In the last couple of days there was a big meeting at the Brookings Institution to celebrate the 40th anniversary of the publication of Arthur Okun's influential 1975 book, Equality and Efficiency: The Big Tradeoff, an idea that went into the textbooks and became a VSP de rigueur truism for quite some time. The conference was asking its relevance today, which it looks like some questioned. Many big cheeses were participating, representing a range of views from Mankiw on the right to Heather Boushey on the left, with Larry Summers making the introductory speech, and Janet Yellen in the audience. But the real question is: Was it ever at all true to begin with?
Mark Thoma provides some quotations from Summers's opening address. He clearly seems to think that the relationship has gone off the rails. The quoted material talks a lot about rising inequality and increasing problems in the financial sector, with the undertow of slower growth and his bugaboo of secular stagnation. Nothing I saw there looked unreasonable. But, again, I am wondering if anybody asked the deeper question in a location where the late Okun was long highly revered, and I think still is. I never met the man, but plenty there think he was just wonderful, and maybe he was. But I think he was never right about this Big Tradeoff, or not very right.
OK, so back in the day we had the Big Poster Boy of communist states with lots of equality, think Maoist China, but not a lot of either growth or high income. Yes, there was certainly an argument there: a society with essentially no incentives to make capital investments or technological innovations, with those incentives maybe leading to greater inequality (and indeed the fall of communism did lead to higher inequality, with China in particular growing rapidly since, an outlier to support Okun's argument, even as many other former socialist states did not do all that well). So, he had some things going for him. But all along there was this problem of Latin America and parts of Africa, with the highest levels of inequality in the world and pretty pathetic growth and income records. This led to an eventual modification of the truism, usually voiced as indeed going against this deep truth, the idea that the relationship between at least per capita income and inequality being an inverted U-shape. It also increasingly was noted that the source of inequality was important, with it coming from being "earned" rather than inherited or through corruption making a big difference.
That the relationship was not all that it was cracked up to be dates back at least to the turn of the century, even among those who ideologically might be inclined to support it. Thus, in 2000 Robert Barro published a paper in the Journal of Economic Growth, Inequality in a panel of countries. He summarized that there is "little overall relation between income inequality and rates of growth and investment." Barro also noted the likely inverted U-shape relationship between per capita income and inequality.
In the previous year, a long paper by Aghion et al in the JEL argued that it looked increasingly like if anything the relationship might be the other way around, with more equal naitons growing more rapidly and programs to increase equality being associated with accelerated growth. They posed the Philippines and South Korea, equal in per capita income in 1960, but with the Philippines having twice the quartile income ratio of South Korea. We know what their subsequent growth records have been.
I would push this forward to note the experience of Latin America, one of the poster boys for high inequality and poor growth performance. During the Great Recession this was arguably the best performing region in the world in terms of growth compared to its several decades past. Curiously, it was the only major region of the world where incomes were becoming more equal, if still more equal than in the rest of the world. This does not prove anything, but then that China fits Okun's story does not prove it, and that nation increasingly looks like a big outlier, quite aside from its decelerating growth rate.
Update: I read the speech by Larry Summerslarrysummers.com/2015/05/04/okuns-equality-and-efficiency at the event. He praise Okun as brilliant, of whom Paul Samuelson basically said that he never said anything incorrect, someone not only insightful in economic policy, but also of philosophical depth. His only comment on how things were back then was that the income distribution did not change. He did not directly comment on the basic issue of whether or not there really was an equality/inefficiency big tradeoff then. He does now think that rising inequality has been linked to slowing growth.
Second Update: Mark Thoma links for 5/6/15 to Heather Boushey's talk at the Brookings conference, and after long discussing how inequality has soared since Okun's day, she finally comes to the same conclusion I do, that Okun was basically wrong and that his legacy is part of our problem today. There never was a Big Tradeoff, just a Big Myth about there being one (latter is my terminology).
Barkley Rosser
Tuesday, May 5, 2015
Osborne-economics
Peter Spence has a long and rambling discussion of the debate in the UK over macroeconomic policy, which includes this from George Osborne:
George Osborne, the Chancellor, has also spoken in defence of the central bank’s aggressive response to the financial crisis. He has argued that a combination of “tight fiscal policy and loose monetary policy is the right macroeconomic mix” to help rebalance the economy.The “right macroeconomic mix” depends on what the question was. Suppose you were an economist working for Reagan’s Council of Economic Advisers in early 1983 when a toxic mix of expansionary fiscal policy offset by incredibly tight monetary policies had sent interest rates soaring and the currency through an incredible real appreciation. Back then the Volcker FED was begging policy to change the macroeconomic mix. Wouldn’t you advise the President to take up the offer? But the UK has been in a very different situation as Paul Krugman explains:
The interesting line, however, is Yates’s note that Britain had relatively high inflation in 2010-2011, which might have meant that the economy faced supply-side rather than demand-side problems, so contractionary policy might have been appropriate. My question is this: even if you accepted that argument, wasn’t that an argument for monetary rather than fiscal contraction? And if the BoE didn’t consider the evidence of overheating sufficient to justify pulling back on its quantitative easing, which had already tripled the size of its balance sheet, why should the Treasury have decided to tighten on its own? After all, the basic logic of the situation is that you should wait until monetary tightening — until the central bank is starting to move off the zero lower bound — before fiscal consolidation. That way you can trade off fiscal tightening for a slower pace of monetary tightening, and avoid deepening the slump. But in 2010-2011 the British central bank wasn’t ready to tighten in any case, so fiscal policy should have waited.But it gets worse when you consider what Peter Spence was writing about:
After a full parliament of near zero interest rates and quantitative easing, some are beginning to wonder whether the nation’s savers have been forgotten. The Bank of England has taken the brunt of the protests, accused of forgetting the interests of the thrifty at best, and at worst of stealing from them by generating inflation.It may be true that low real interest rates have led to lower portfolio income for certain savers but this is not the doing of the Bank of England as it was the stupid decision to pursue fiscal austerity that kept UK economic growth low, which induced the Bank of England to do the right thing – lower interest rates. Had the Cameron government not engaged in this fiscal austerity, the UK economy would be closer to full employment which would likely mean higher real interest rate might be a reasonable monetary policy.
Saturday, May 2, 2015
Dark Matter or Base Erosion & Profit Shifting?
Tim Taylor provides some interesting data but I think his discussion fell short:
Here's the evolution of US net international investment position, as shown by the size of foreign assets and liabilities, in the last few years … In the last few years, the gap between US assets and liabilities has clearly been rising.Tim cites the latest from the BEA which indicates that the U.S. holds $24.6 trillion in foreign assets while foreigners hold $31.6 trillion in our assets. So we have net debtor position equal $7 trillion at these recorded values. BEA’s Table 4.1 - Foreign Transactions in the National Income and Product Accounts – shows that we received $0.8 trillion in income on our holdings of foreign assets while foreigners receive only $0.6 trillion. What to make of this fact that the return on our holdings of foreign assets is 3.25% while foreigners receive only a 1.9% return? Tim notes this simply as:
US investors abroad are more likely to make higher-risk, higher-return investments in equities or ownership of foreign assets.Ricardo Hausmann and Frederico Sturzenegger took the income flows reported by BEA and discounted them by 5%, which was the long-term government bond rate back then. If we updated their Dark Matter story using a 2% government bond rate representing current market conditions, the value of our holdings of foreign assets would be $40 trillion whereas the value of the U.S. assets held by foreigners would be only $10 trillion. In other words, they might argue that this is $17 trillion in Dark Matter. Willem Buiter’s Cold Fushion casts serious doubts about this Dark Matter as did BEA’s Ralph Kozlow. Kozlow’s transfer pricing story is still on the BEA website:
Transactions between foreign direct investors and their U.S. affiliates may occur at prices (“transfer prices”) that result in the U.S. affiliates recording low profits. Earnings on foreign direct investments, while still relatively low, have grown briskly over the last few years. Is the rate of return for foreign direct investment in the U.S. artificially low because foreign direct investors understate their U.S. profits through transfer pricing? Some researchers have argued that transfer pricing explains why the rate of return that foreign investors earn on their direct investments in the U.S. is lower than what U.S. investors earn on their direct investments abroad.Kozlow also credits a paper by Daniel Gros. The OECD Base Erosion & Profit Shifting crowd is interested in these issues as Action Plan 11 states:
Establish methodologies to collect and analyse data on BEPS and the actions to address it. Specifically to: Develop recommendations regarding indicators of the scale and economic impact of BEPS and ensure that tools are available to monitor and evaluate the effectiveness and economic impact of the actions taken to address BEPS on an ongoing basis. This will involve developing an economic analysis of the scale and impact of BEPS (including spillover effects across countries) and actions to address it. The work will also involve assessing a range of existing data sources, identifying new types of data that should be collected, and developing methodologies based on both aggregate (e.g. FDI and balance of payments data) and micro-level data (e.g. from financial statements and tax returns), taking into consideration the need to respect taxpayer confidentiality and the administrative costs for tax administrations and businesses.This strikes me as an incredibly ambitious agenda. If anyone knows of an update to the Buiter-Gros-Kozlow insights, this could prove very useful.
Redaction
A funny word this, "redaction." In French, a redacteur is an editor. In English, redaction means "editing,"although we do not use "redactor" at all. However, increasingly this word has come to mean a particular form of editing, in particular a removal of text containing information that the editor does not want to publish. Increasingly the reasons for such redaction is indefensible, immoral even. I am tempted to quote Steve Waldman of Baltimore, aka, Interfluidity, who, when talking about superficial commentators on the Baltimore riots said, "Fuck you, go to hell."
The term has been taken over by the US intelligence establishment. You file a Freedom of Information Act request? Well, if you hit the right topic or set of reports, good chance it will come back covered with black marks that cover up much of what you were looking for, in some cases including nearly everything on the requested report, essentially undoing the whole point of the FOIA, ha ha! So much is so important to the national security, just like in Vladimir Putin's Russia. You want the truth? We have those Very Serious Black Marks of Redaction for You.
At a much lower level we have in scholarly research this problem also increasingly an issue. There the problem is less frequently matters of national security and big bad government agencies roaring in, although that does occur for sure, but concerns over legal vulnerability, that someone or other might sue the publisher if an inappropriate thing is published that might upset somebody. Freedom of speech? Academic freedom? Naah. The protection of worthless fucking assholes who are known to be litigious (or are suspected of being so) is far more important than the truth. We must keep our priorities straight.
So, let me make this both personal and professional. I am the author of a chapter in Secrets of Economics Editors, MIT Press fairly recently, with a completely incompetent and stupid review by Robert Moffitt in the latest JEL Several of the essays in there have caused stirs to various degrees, with the one by William Barnett about the fracturing between the Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, the Review of Economic Dynamics, and Macroeconomic Dynamics (which he edits and founded) being an example, which involves central disputes over macroeconomics, as well as problems in publishing and editing journals.
So, my chapter's short title is "Secrets from the Crypt," and one can find the unredacted unexpurgated version that has been used in various considerations that I cannot publicly reveal. It has been around, and you can read it on my website at http://cob.jmu.edu/rosserjb. However, that is not all that close to what appears in the book. The version in the book has a much shorter second half, also leading to a bibliography cut in half, redacted on advice of MIT Press attorneys to avoid possible lawsuits by "Professor X." That Professor X is a completely worthless and disgusting piece of scum will be quite clear to anybody who reads even the redacted version in the book, although the unredacted version really hammers this fact in.
I shall add a bit more not in either version, which involves the econoblogosphere. After Professor X sent out his mass messages, I replied to relevant parties about my position on the matter. One of those on the receiving end of my reply is a good friend of a major blogger with NY Times connections. He asked me if he could send all of it to this blogger and thus to the Times. I replied that he should not as this was what Professor X wanted, to have his worthless claims put into a "He said, she said," framework, as in the old, "Professor A says the earth is round, but Professor B argues that it might be flat." I knew that the victims of Professor X's scurrilous attacks did not want this situation to result, and I agreed, and I am grateful that the person who asked me this agreed, and this did not become more public. As it is, Professor X, who really is a big fat zero, has all but disappeared in terms of academic or any other discourse, and those whom he tormented have been liberated from his baseless attacks.
OTOH, I must recognize that in this situation, I myself exercised redaction. Who am I therefore to raise questions about its possibly excessive use?
Barkley Rosser
The term has been taken over by the US intelligence establishment. You file a Freedom of Information Act request? Well, if you hit the right topic or set of reports, good chance it will come back covered with black marks that cover up much of what you were looking for, in some cases including nearly everything on the requested report, essentially undoing the whole point of the FOIA, ha ha! So much is so important to the national security, just like in Vladimir Putin's Russia. You want the truth? We have those Very Serious Black Marks of Redaction for You.
At a much lower level we have in scholarly research this problem also increasingly an issue. There the problem is less frequently matters of national security and big bad government agencies roaring in, although that does occur for sure, but concerns over legal vulnerability, that someone or other might sue the publisher if an inappropriate thing is published that might upset somebody. Freedom of speech? Academic freedom? Naah. The protection of worthless fucking assholes who are known to be litigious (or are suspected of being so) is far more important than the truth. We must keep our priorities straight.
So, let me make this both personal and professional. I am the author of a chapter in Secrets of Economics Editors, MIT Press fairly recently, with a completely incompetent and stupid review by Robert Moffitt in the latest JEL Several of the essays in there have caused stirs to various degrees, with the one by William Barnett about the fracturing between the Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, the Review of Economic Dynamics, and Macroeconomic Dynamics (which he edits and founded) being an example, which involves central disputes over macroeconomics, as well as problems in publishing and editing journals.
So, my chapter's short title is "Secrets from the Crypt," and one can find the unredacted unexpurgated version that has been used in various considerations that I cannot publicly reveal. It has been around, and you can read it on my website at http://cob.jmu.edu/rosserjb. However, that is not all that close to what appears in the book. The version in the book has a much shorter second half, also leading to a bibliography cut in half, redacted on advice of MIT Press attorneys to avoid possible lawsuits by "Professor X." That Professor X is a completely worthless and disgusting piece of scum will be quite clear to anybody who reads even the redacted version in the book, although the unredacted version really hammers this fact in.
I shall add a bit more not in either version, which involves the econoblogosphere. After Professor X sent out his mass messages, I replied to relevant parties about my position on the matter. One of those on the receiving end of my reply is a good friend of a major blogger with NY Times connections. He asked me if he could send all of it to this blogger and thus to the Times. I replied that he should not as this was what Professor X wanted, to have his worthless claims put into a "He said, she said," framework, as in the old, "Professor A says the earth is round, but Professor B argues that it might be flat." I knew that the victims of Professor X's scurrilous attacks did not want this situation to result, and I agreed, and I am grateful that the person who asked me this agreed, and this did not become more public. As it is, Professor X, who really is a big fat zero, has all but disappeared in terms of academic or any other discourse, and those whom he tormented have been liberated from his baseless attacks.
OTOH, I must recognize that in this situation, I myself exercised redaction. Who am I therefore to raise questions about its possibly excessive use?
Barkley Rosser
Friday, May 1, 2015
May Day! May Day! Arise, ye prisoners of starvation...
"Ultimately, the trend toward widening inequality in America, as elsewhere, can be reversed only if the vast majority, whose incomes have stagnated and whose wealth has failed to increase, join together to demand fundamental change." -- Bob ReichWorkers of the world, unite. What kind of fundamental change does Bob Reich have in mind? Giving workers "the bargaining leverage they need to get a larger share of the gains from growth."
Full employment was a substitute for collective action. Growth was a substitute for full employment. "We're all in this together" sacrifice (austerity) was a substitute for growth. Collective action to get a larger share of the gains from growth begins to sound like the conservative motto, "a fair day's wage for a fair day's work."
“Workers ought not to be exclusively absorbed in these unavoidable guerilla fights incessantly springing up from the never ceasing encroachments of capital or changes of the market. They ought to understand that, with all the miseries it imposes upon them, the present system simultaneously engenders the material conditions and the social forms necessary for an economical reconstruction of society. Instead of the conservative motto, ‘A fair day's wage for a fair day's work!’ they ought to inscribe on their banner the revolutionary watchword, ‘Abolition of the wages system!’”
Full Employment, Growth and Immiseration
Once upon a time there was full employment. Full employment after the war, to be exact.
And then there was "growth." Not exactly the same idea as full employment but there was a compelling resemblance.
At last we have arrived at "expansionary contraction" -- otherwise known as austerity (formerly referred to as immiseration). And they all lived happily ever after?
Or we could mind the gaps.
And then there was "growth." Not exactly the same idea as full employment but there was a compelling resemblance.
At last we have arrived at "expansionary contraction" -- otherwise known as austerity (formerly referred to as immiseration). And they all lived happily ever after?
Now, none of the things is "just like" the others. But we can talk about them as if they were "equal in exchange value.".
Thursday, April 30, 2015
"They wonder why they are working longer hours for lower wages..."
EXPERT DECRIES CUT IN WORK WEEK
Study Finds Reduction Won't Necessarily Create Jobs
Special to The New York Times
ITHACA, N. Y. Jan. 4—A reduction in the number of working hours a week in American industry will not necessarily create more jobs, a study recently completed by a former research assistant at Cornell's New York State School of Industrial and Labor Relations has found.In a bulletin, "The Shorter Work Week," issued by the school, Marcia L. Greenbaum has reported that the 40-hour work week is likely to disappear, but much more gradually than many labor leaders seem to want.
Miss Greenbaum notes that many of the nation's labor leaders believe that a 35-hour week with the same weekly pay now earned for 40 hours of work and double time for overtime will help to solve the problem of unemployment. However, she has pointed out that to maintain take-home pay will require a 14.3 per cent wage increase.
In turn, she reported, this will mean an increase in management's labor costs that, in highly competitive industries will require the laying off of workers, increasing productivity and a passing on of costs to consumers.
Her study, she reports, found that management and Government officials contend that a shorter work week at the same pay would probably mean a drop in living standards.
"The 14.3 per cent wage increase is almost five times more than the normal annual productivity increase of 3 per cent," Miss Greenbaum said. "Productivity would have to increase as much as wages increase to prevent inflation."
She added that, as a result, "real wages would be less since rising prices would mean higher living costs." The shorter work week would also lead, Miss Greenbaum reported, to a probable increase in moonlighting and an increase in the labor force of secondary workers such as housewives and retired workers.
"There are other ways of decreasing hours of work, such as longer weekends, longer vacations and' earlier retirement ages," Miss Greenbaum reported. She also suggested sabbatical leaves for older employes.
The above article appeared on page 94 of the January 4, 1964 New York Times. Here is how the "former research assistant" Marcia Greenbaum summarized her chapter on the economic implications of the shorter work week:
If this chapter has painted a gloomy picture of the economic implications of the shorter workweek, it is simply reflecting the nearly unanimous opinion of economists outside of the labor movement. Every other labor proposal for coping with unemployment -- such as the AFL-CIO's recommendations concerning tax cuts, public works, aid to depressed areas, and retraining the unemployed-receives support from at least some economists and public officials. In their plea for shorter hours, however, union leaders stand alone, attacked even by the leading officials of a friendly Administration.
Labor's arguments are simple and straightforward. If the government can not solve the severe unemployment problem, then unions must devise some method of inducing individual employers to hire more workers. If an employer can work each employee only 35 instead of 40 hours a week, then it is believed that he will hire more employees to make up the lost production. At the same time, labor claims, purchasing power can be maintained, or even increased, by requiring that weekly pay be kept at the 40-hour level.
The objections to the shorter workweek, we have seen, center almost entirely on its cost impact. If hours are reduced in one large jump, labor's insistence upon maintaining weekly take-home pay means that the employer is faced with a huge hourly wage increase and perhaps some other costs as well. In that event, it is assumed that the employer will attempt to offset these increased costs by raising prices or taking other action that will most likely result in no net employment increase and might even cause a loss of more jobs. On the other hand, if labor asks only that shorter hours be introduced gradually, in step with productivity increases, then again the employer has no incentive to hire any additional workers, for nothing has happened either to his costs or to his demand.
As labor leaders point out, the majority of economists have often been wrong before and perhaps they are wrong again on this issue. Until experience proves otherwise, however, prevailing opinion is that the shorter workweek is not the answer to the very real problem of unemployment which has plagued our economy in recent years.
The April, 1966, Labor Law Journal carried an article by Howard G. Foster, "a Teaching Assistant at the New York State School of Industrial and Labor Relations" that quoted the first paragraph of the above passage from Greenbaum's bulletin. Rather than simply citing what "management and Government officials contend" and the "nearly unanimous opinion of economists," Foster did the math. There was no report on Foster's findings in the New York Times. Not even on page 94.
Wednesday, April 29, 2015
The Saudi Royal Family Shakeup
So, new Saudi King Salman, using the official channel of the 35-member Allegiance Council, has shaken up the top leadership of the royal family, most particularly the kingship succession itself. Out as next in line is now former Crown Prince Muqrin, the youngest of the "First Generation" of sons of the kingdom's founder, Abdulaziz, aka "Ibn Saud." The second generation now former Deputy Crown Prince (the #2 spot), Prince Mohammed bin Nayef, a full nephew of the king, and the first of the Second Generation to be put in line for the throne, has replaced Muqrin as Crown Prince. His position has now been filled by the much younger son of Salman, Mohammed bin Salman, currently Defense Minister. It is unclear what is behind this, although reportedly Muqrin "requested" to step down. Somehow I doubt that. There has been so far no speculation on why this has happened anywhere that I have seen, including the highly knowledgeable blogs, Crossroads Arabia, where only the bare facts have been reported, or Juan Cole, who has so far had nothing to say about this at all.
So, my quick speculation is that this involves cementing the royal succession into the hands of descendants of the so-called "Sudeiri Seven," of whom Salman is the last one living. Always very powerful, they were the sons of the favorite wife of the late Abdulaziz, Assa as-Sudeiri, reported to be his first cousin, or at least some sort of relative. It was rumored that near the end of her life in the early 80s she was actually running the country from her deathbed through her powerful sons, whom she reportedly totally dominated. This just goes to show that in a totally sexist society, a woman can achieve great power by having powerful sons whom she dominates, an iron matriarch, and she was it, sort of like the dowager empress of China, Cixi, in the late 19th century.
Muqrin's weakness on this front was reported even back when he was first appointed at the time of the succession of Salman on the death of former King Abdullah a few months ago. His problem? A low class concubine mother, no match for the formidable, if long dead, Assa as-Sudeiri. I suspect that there were other factors, with the general closeness of Salman of the newly appointed. But Muqrin was clearly vulnerable due to his mother. I presume we shall learn more sometime eventually about what other factors may have been involved here, although some observers note that both of the guys now in line are more or less hardliners in the burgeoning conflict with Iran and such places as Yemen (indeed, I think that Muqrin had some sort of Yemeni links, which probably did not help him).
Another shift is the final stepping down after 40 years as foreign minister, Saud bin Faisal bin Abdulaziz al Sa'ud, aka "Saud al Faisal." This was for health reasons, and in his last public appearance about a month ago, he was using a walker and looked in pretty bad shape. However, he is not gone form the scene, apparently now being appointed a minister without portfolio and senior adviser to King Salman. Many thought he should have been the first of the Second Generation to be king, but he was too old and ill, not to be. He is being succeeded by the current ambassador to the US, Adel al-Jubeir, not a member of royal family.
A curious fact is that since the official formation of the Saudi foreign ministry in 1930, either Saud or his late father the former King Faisal, served as foreign minister for 83 of the 85 years since that time. Indeed, while it had not been officially formed, Faisal had effectively held that position for the 11 years prior to the formation of the ministry, having represented his father at the Versailles Treaty conference in 1919 when he was all of a whopping 16 years old. If you see a photo of him then, you will be looking at just about the oldest and most serious looking 16 year old you will ever see.
The only two years they were not in that position was 196-62, when Faisal was trying to overthrow his older brother, the corrupt and incompetent Saud, who had succeeded their father. When he succeeded, he retook that position even as he became king, holding it until his assassination by a nephew in 1975, when his son, Saud, succeeded him, lasting in it until today. Many consider Faisal to have been the most intelligent and competent of the 43 sons of Abdulaziz, and Saud may well be the same for all of his grandsons. (The guy who served as FM in 60-62 was an obscure non-royal family member, Ibrahim bin Abdullah al-Sowaiyel.)
Barkley Rosser
Update: Based on press reports, a bit mroe is clear. Probably the main reason Prince Muqrin is out is that he had been chosen by the former king, Abdullah, and is clsoe to sons of Abdullah. Hence, this is very much about putting the line of succession into the hands of the Sudeiris and especially keeping the sons of Abduallah out of the line of succession. There have also been reports about how strong the new guys are on national security and how independtne of the US they are. But, this is a joke in that Muqurin also has strong national security credentials, and when the new Crown Prince was first named Deputy Crown Prince after Abdullah's death, his closeness to US officials was stressed. This is internatl family politics, pure and simple.
Another Update: WaPo has an editorial for May 4 I largely agree with on all this. They again fail to note the intra-family politics of this, but they do accurately note that no one should expect improvements in human rights in Saudi Arabia from this shakeup. The only woman in the cabinet, a deputy minister of education, has been removed, and the highly repressive religious police have had restrictions on their activities removed. This probably reflects the elevation of the new Crown Prince, who is Minister of the Interior, following his later father, both of them noted as hardliners on such issues.
So, my quick speculation is that this involves cementing the royal succession into the hands of descendants of the so-called "Sudeiri Seven," of whom Salman is the last one living. Always very powerful, they were the sons of the favorite wife of the late Abdulaziz, Assa as-Sudeiri, reported to be his first cousin, or at least some sort of relative. It was rumored that near the end of her life in the early 80s she was actually running the country from her deathbed through her powerful sons, whom she reportedly totally dominated. This just goes to show that in a totally sexist society, a woman can achieve great power by having powerful sons whom she dominates, an iron matriarch, and she was it, sort of like the dowager empress of China, Cixi, in the late 19th century.
Muqrin's weakness on this front was reported even back when he was first appointed at the time of the succession of Salman on the death of former King Abdullah a few months ago. His problem? A low class concubine mother, no match for the formidable, if long dead, Assa as-Sudeiri. I suspect that there were other factors, with the general closeness of Salman of the newly appointed. But Muqrin was clearly vulnerable due to his mother. I presume we shall learn more sometime eventually about what other factors may have been involved here, although some observers note that both of the guys now in line are more or less hardliners in the burgeoning conflict with Iran and such places as Yemen (indeed, I think that Muqrin had some sort of Yemeni links, which probably did not help him).
Another shift is the final stepping down after 40 years as foreign minister, Saud bin Faisal bin Abdulaziz al Sa'ud, aka "Saud al Faisal." This was for health reasons, and in his last public appearance about a month ago, he was using a walker and looked in pretty bad shape. However, he is not gone form the scene, apparently now being appointed a minister without portfolio and senior adviser to King Salman. Many thought he should have been the first of the Second Generation to be king, but he was too old and ill, not to be. He is being succeeded by the current ambassador to the US, Adel al-Jubeir, not a member of royal family.
A curious fact is that since the official formation of the Saudi foreign ministry in 1930, either Saud or his late father the former King Faisal, served as foreign minister for 83 of the 85 years since that time. Indeed, while it had not been officially formed, Faisal had effectively held that position for the 11 years prior to the formation of the ministry, having represented his father at the Versailles Treaty conference in 1919 when he was all of a whopping 16 years old. If you see a photo of him then, you will be looking at just about the oldest and most serious looking 16 year old you will ever see.
The only two years they were not in that position was 196-62, when Faisal was trying to overthrow his older brother, the corrupt and incompetent Saud, who had succeeded their father. When he succeeded, he retook that position even as he became king, holding it until his assassination by a nephew in 1975, when his son, Saud, succeeded him, lasting in it until today. Many consider Faisal to have been the most intelligent and competent of the 43 sons of Abdulaziz, and Saud may well be the same for all of his grandsons. (The guy who served as FM in 60-62 was an obscure non-royal family member, Ibrahim bin Abdullah al-Sowaiyel.)
Barkley Rosser
Update: Based on press reports, a bit mroe is clear. Probably the main reason Prince Muqrin is out is that he had been chosen by the former king, Abdullah, and is clsoe to sons of Abdullah. Hence, this is very much about putting the line of succession into the hands of the Sudeiris and especially keeping the sons of Abduallah out of the line of succession. There have also been reports about how strong the new guys are on national security and how independtne of the US they are. But, this is a joke in that Muqurin also has strong national security credentials, and when the new Crown Prince was first named Deputy Crown Prince after Abdullah's death, his closeness to US officials was stressed. This is internatl family politics, pure and simple.
Another Update: WaPo has an editorial for May 4 I largely agree with on all this. They again fail to note the intra-family politics of this, but they do accurately note that no one should expect improvements in human rights in Saudi Arabia from this shakeup. The only woman in the cabinet, a deputy minister of education, has been removed, and the highly repressive religious police have had restrictions on their activities removed. This probably reflects the elevation of the new Crown Prince, who is Minister of the Interior, following his later father, both of them noted as hardliners on such issues.
Puzzling in America
Technology and Jobs: Should Workers Worry?
Responding to a question from Maryland at 46:20:
Barro: "...you could have a gradual decline in hours worked per week by a full-time employee and a gradual decline in the number of years that people participate in the labor force and that would do a lot on the labor supply side to deal with declines in labor demand..."
Delong: "And in America it's puzzling we haven't... right? That we've been stuck at forty hours a week as full time or so since world war II even though there's been 75 years since then..."
Writing in Fortune magazine 61 years ago, Daniel Seligman predicted achievement of the four-day week by 1980. He based that prediction on projection of historical trends. It didn't happen.
The future of work has a chequered past.
"And in America it's puzzling we haven't... right?"
Wrong. It's only puzzling if you don't know anything about the role of American economists in opposing, castigating and ridiculing proposals for work time reduction ("economists call it the lump of labor fallacy -- the idea that there is only a fixed amount of work to be done").
Larry Summers remembers: "when I was an undergraduate at MIT in the 1960s there was a whole round of concern about this -- will automation displace all the employment? And what I was taught as an undergraduate was that basically the people who thought it would were a bunch of idiot Luddites and that obviously there would eventually be enough demand and it would all sort of work itself out, and if people got more productive they'd be richer and they'd spend and maybe we needed some transition assistance, but that it was all basically going to be okay. That was what I was taught."
Puzzle solved!
Lowballing Estimates of Potential Output
Simon Wren Lewis notes one of the Cameron excuses for fiscal austerity:
As I noted in my previous post, the very big government budget deficit in 2010 was largely the result of the recession. That fact is difficult to square with the myth that the coalition government rescued the economy from an impending financial crisis, so it is important to push another explanation for the large deficit: that it reflected the profligacy of the previous government.The Great Recession increased the deficits for a lot of nations including those that undertook the Herbert Hoover economics of fiscal austerity during a period of weak aggregate demand. Over 60 years ago, E. Cary Brown noted that an analyst needs to separate the automatic stabilizer effects on the actual deficit from changes in fiscal policy. This is often accomplished by examining the structural surplus (deficit). Simon also notes:
The only way you can sustain the myth that Labour was fiscally profligate is by suggesting that immediately before the recession the UK was experiencing a massive boom. In an economic boom tax receipts are high and spending on transfers low, so the budget should be in surplus. If it is in fact in significant deficit, that indicates serious fiscal laxity.He continued with a criticism of how the IMF changed it estimate of the UK’s potential output, which we also noted. Simon’s latest continues the discussion:
The first point is to stop talking about GDP, and start talking about GDP per head ... As the chart shows, we have failed as yet to make up for any of the ground lost not just in the 2009 recession, but also ground lost as a result of fiscal austerity in 2010 and 2011 … So we have not really seen a recovery. Maybe the pessimists are right, and we will never recover any of that lost output, but still you do not call it a recovery. I can put it another way. Quarterly growth in GDP per head since the beginning of 2013 has averaged about 2% at an annual rate. That is below the average growth rate since 1955. A recovery from a deep recession would have growth rates well above the long term average … the prosperity of the average citizen in this country has hardly increased over the period of this coalition government - a result that is totally unprecedented since at least WWII. As recoveries from recessions go, this does not seem like a recovery worthy of the name. Yet we keep being told by mediamacro that the Coalition’s strong card is its economic record!As we noted when we presented Bill Martin’s aggregate demand explanation versus the productivity pessimist story: Bill comes down on the latter explanation as does Paul and Simon. The former view is a Real Business Cycle tale of negative productivity shocks. We heard those stories 30 years ago but the US economy finally did fully recover. Let’s hope the same occurs for the UK economy. But let’s suppose for a moment that the productivity pessimists are correct. Then Cameron’s government should cease gloating how well the UK economy is doing as a permanent fall in real income per capita is not good news. Let me just add that if this productivity pessimism argument was valid, the expansionary monetary policy from the Bank of England should have been inflationary. But the record shows it was not. Paul Krugman adds a lot more but I found this part of interest:
Chart 3 shows estimates of our old friend the cyclically adjusted primary balance since 2009. I’ve included three sources – the IMF, the OECD, and Britain’s own Office of Budget Responsibility – just in case someone wants to argue that any one of these sources is biased. In fact, every one tells the same story: big spending cuts and a large tax rise between 2009 and 2011, not much change thereafter.Paul’s chart 3 were drawn from three measures of the cyclically adjusted primary balance that assumed the UK output gap was severely negative in 2007 even if Paul noted why these measures were likely low balling potential GDP. Of course, fiscal impact is about the change in fiscal policy but leave the UK for now. We are having a few debates about U.S. monetary policy and inflation that revolve around low ball estimates of potential GDP. Our two graphs show how I would estimate the output gap for two 7 year periods, which is by using the CBO estimate of potential GDP. John Taylor has been at this argument for way too long:
the Fed has returned to its discretionary, unpredictable ways, and the results are not good. Starting in 2003-05, it held interest rates too low for too long and thereby encouraged excessive risk-taking and the housing boom.There have been a lot of effective rebuttals to this claim. Our first graph suggests that we did not see the output gap disappear until the end of 2005 and the period of excessive demand was very short lived and was already being offset by the FED’s increase in interest rates. Yet we see this canard:
There are multiple measures of the output gap that show the U.S. economy overheating during this time. Below is a figure from this article that compares the real-time and final measures of the U.S. output gap. Everyone shows ex-post an overheating economy during the housing boom.David Beckworth had earlier argued we were witnesses a series of positive productivity shocks and yet he wants to argue the CBO overestimated potential output. Something does not add up. Our second graph relates to something from perhaps the last honest supply-sider - Bruce Bartlett:
In this article, the author reviews the continuing controversy over the Reagan tax cut. Republicans often assert that it was so expansionary that there was no revenue loss, something the Reagan administration itself never claimed. The truth is that the tax cut lost a lot of revenue, but helped the economy transition from high inflation to low inflation at an unexpectedly low economic cost.Paul Krugman rightfully points to the first part of this as evidence that the three stooges (Lawrence Kudlow, Art Laffer, and Stephen Moore) misrepresent the 1980’s record but I would question Bruce’s claim that the economic cost of the disinflation was low. In fact Paul noted that the cost was expected:
Keynesians came into the Volcker disinflation — yes, it was mainly the Fed’s doing, not Reagan’s — with a standard, indeed textbook, model of what should happen. And events matched their expectations almost precisely.Using the CBO measure of potential GDP during the 1980’s, the Volcker disinflation involved what Paul calls a PLOG – a prolonged large output gap.
Truthiness, media framing and the political economy of economics
Concealed deep in the bowels of the ivory tower is this little-known academic endeavor sometimes referred to as "political economy of communications." These guys study "media bias" or "media framing." They've even done content analysis that goes beyond harping at the very serious personhood of this or that individual columnist or newspaper.
For example, in Framed! Labor and the Corporate Media, Christopher Martin identified Five Dominant Frames in the media coverage of labor disputes:
Has it ever occurred to anyone that the dominance in elite economics of a particular economic ideology may owe more to the dominance of a congenial corporate media frame than to any inherent theoretical elegance or empirical support? Of course not.
There is this peculiar rhetorical mise en abyme in which editorial punditry takes its Delphic authority from what "economists say" while what they say simply regurgitates something they read (over and over again) in the press.
"I'm an economist and I'm O.K. I say what I've been told that 'economists say'."
Wouldn't it be worthwhile to ask whether the economics practiced today is, in effect, a subsidiary of the corporate mass media rather than an independent academic discipline?
For example, in Framed! Labor and the Corporate Media, Christopher Martin identified Five Dominant Frames in the media coverage of labor disputes:
(1) The consumer is king;Stated somewhat more evasively, these also happen to be the tenets of the dominant frame in contemporary economics -- the "equilibrium price-auction view of the world" (aka subjective preference theory or conservative ideal). Surprise, surprise!
(2) The process of production is none of the public’s business;
(3) The economy is driven by great business leaders and entrepreneurs;
(4) The workplace is a meritocracy; and
(5) Collective economic action is bad.
Has it ever occurred to anyone that the dominance in elite economics of a particular economic ideology may owe more to the dominance of a congenial corporate media frame than to any inherent theoretical elegance or empirical support? Of course not.
There is this peculiar rhetorical mise en abyme in which editorial punditry takes its Delphic authority from what "economists say" while what they say simply regurgitates something they read (over and over again) in the press.
"I'm an economist and I'm O.K. I say what I've been told that 'economists say'."
Wouldn't it be worthwhile to ask whether the economics practiced today is, in effect, a subsidiary of the corporate mass media rather than an independent academic discipline?
Tuesday, April 28, 2015
Allan Sloan Joins The WaPo VSP Truthiness Gang On Social Security
Allan Sloan, semi-retired from the Washington Post wrote a report today entitled "Soaking the 'rich' won't fix Social Security." In it he announces that he is "launching what I hope will become a series of Social Security truth-teller articles." He poses himself as in the obviously Very Serious Center between "conservatives [who] agitate to cut benefits and liberals [who] agitate to raise them." Unfortunately his first outing makes it look like he is engaging more in truthiness like so many other VSPs at WaPo whom he seems to be joining, such as Fred Hiatt, Robert J. Samuelson, and Ruth Marcus, all of whom regularly bloviate obsessively on all the things that should be done to Social Security because it is so awful and messed up. Sloan appears to be joining their Truthiness Gang.
His targets in this article are Chris Christie on the right who wants to reduce benefits for those earning over $80,000 per year, with those earning over $200,000, and Elizabeth Warren on the left, who wants to raise benefits and also raise the maximum wage cap for paying the fica, currently at $118,500. What has him really steamed is a general idea he claims they both share that "the rich" are getting too sweet a deal out of Social Security as of now.
His evidence in his "fact-filled" report for this is an estimate he had done by Social Security actuaries on his and his wfe's own situation, with them having been at the max wage cap for 35 years. Apparently according to this, no details on how this was calculated, the current value of their future [expected] benefits is only 75% of what they paid in, with this lowered further by his working longer and having in the future to pay taxes on his benefits. While one could argue about this calculation, I shall not do so. Let this be his big fact from which he argues that "the rich," or those whose wage incomes exceed the max wage and thus do not pay more in fica than anybody else at the max wage or above, are actually getting the shaft.
Now, I shall give him credit that in fact he agrees that it is not unreasonable that the Social Security system be on net a moderately progressive system, taking account of both taxes and benefits, and in fact this has been known for decades based on studies by people like my major professor, Eugene Smolensky and others dating back at least to the 1970s and re-confirmed since. This is not really news, even if Sloan thinks it is.
The problem comes later, in particular when he conflates in the end the political bottom line of what Christie and Warren propose. His final paragraph declares, "Either of these turns Social Security from an earned benefit that is subtly means-tested into welfare. And we all know what tends to happen to welfare in this country." Ooops!
Clearly what is involved here is a matter of perception above all, and on how Christie's proposal will be perceived, simply paying no benefits at all to people above a certain income level, that is indeed how it will be perceived: that Social Security will have become "welfare." Indeed, this is why liberals have consistently opposed doing that, with it not at all surprising that is someone on the right, even if on the center-right, who has put this forward. It is a recipe for draining support from the program over time.
But the proposal of Warren, with or without a benefits increase, and with or without some general lowering of the fica tax rate that could be done if the max wage cap is raised so as to still make at least current revenues, does not lead to that outcome. As Sloan admits, the program already is mildly progressive, and thus if one wishes to push it, already sort of a "welfare" program. But it is not perceived as such. Yes, raising the cap, whatever else is done, pushes the program more in that direction, makes it more progressive, more of a welfare program, but does not fundamentally and qualitatively change it from what it is now. I would contend, and I really do not see how Sloan can claim otherwise, as long as higher income people get the benefits that they have always gotten, with no reduction in that for them, I doubt that many of them will view Social Security as having become a "welfare program." They may not like the tax hike and oppose it, but as long as they get those benefits, they will not call it a welfare program because they are getting those benefits, and if there is anything a rich person does not like being called, it is a welfare recipient.
Sloan is going to have to do better than this if he is going to avoid simply being another member of the pathetic and egregious WaPo Social Security Truthiness Gang.
Barkley Rosser
So,
His targets in this article are Chris Christie on the right who wants to reduce benefits for those earning over $80,000 per year, with those earning over $200,000, and Elizabeth Warren on the left, who wants to raise benefits and also raise the maximum wage cap for paying the fica, currently at $118,500. What has him really steamed is a general idea he claims they both share that "the rich" are getting too sweet a deal out of Social Security as of now.
His evidence in his "fact-filled" report for this is an estimate he had done by Social Security actuaries on his and his wfe's own situation, with them having been at the max wage cap for 35 years. Apparently according to this, no details on how this was calculated, the current value of their future [expected] benefits is only 75% of what they paid in, with this lowered further by his working longer and having in the future to pay taxes on his benefits. While one could argue about this calculation, I shall not do so. Let this be his big fact from which he argues that "the rich," or those whose wage incomes exceed the max wage and thus do not pay more in fica than anybody else at the max wage or above, are actually getting the shaft.
Now, I shall give him credit that in fact he agrees that it is not unreasonable that the Social Security system be on net a moderately progressive system, taking account of both taxes and benefits, and in fact this has been known for decades based on studies by people like my major professor, Eugene Smolensky and others dating back at least to the 1970s and re-confirmed since. This is not really news, even if Sloan thinks it is.
The problem comes later, in particular when he conflates in the end the political bottom line of what Christie and Warren propose. His final paragraph declares, "Either of these turns Social Security from an earned benefit that is subtly means-tested into welfare. And we all know what tends to happen to welfare in this country." Ooops!
Clearly what is involved here is a matter of perception above all, and on how Christie's proposal will be perceived, simply paying no benefits at all to people above a certain income level, that is indeed how it will be perceived: that Social Security will have become "welfare." Indeed, this is why liberals have consistently opposed doing that, with it not at all surprising that is someone on the right, even if on the center-right, who has put this forward. It is a recipe for draining support from the program over time.
But the proposal of Warren, with or without a benefits increase, and with or without some general lowering of the fica tax rate that could be done if the max wage cap is raised so as to still make at least current revenues, does not lead to that outcome. As Sloan admits, the program already is mildly progressive, and thus if one wishes to push it, already sort of a "welfare" program. But it is not perceived as such. Yes, raising the cap, whatever else is done, pushes the program more in that direction, makes it more progressive, more of a welfare program, but does not fundamentally and qualitatively change it from what it is now. I would contend, and I really do not see how Sloan can claim otherwise, as long as higher income people get the benefits that they have always gotten, with no reduction in that for them, I doubt that many of them will view Social Security as having become a "welfare program." They may not like the tax hike and oppose it, but as long as they get those benefits, they will not call it a welfare program because they are getting those benefits, and if there is anything a rich person does not like being called, it is a welfare recipient.
Sloan is going to have to do better than this if he is going to avoid simply being another member of the pathetic and egregious WaPo Social Security Truthiness Gang.
Barkley Rosser
So,
Why Varoufakis’ Job Was Impossible
As Greek finance minister, Yanis Varoufakis has had two responsibilities. First, Greece’s strategy hinged on a public relations effort directed at the citizenry of other eurozone countries, to convince them that austerity has functioned as a downward vortex in Europe, and that human decency requires a resumption of growth and social provision in Greece. Realistically or not, Syriza has counted on grassroots political pressure to counter the orthodoxy of “the institutions”. Varoufakis was the main public face of this campaign.
Second, as finance minister, Varoufakis was the point person in negotiations with peers from the other countries. Diplomatic etiquette, again rightly or wrongly, requires a limited public presence and clubby, consensus-building behavior behind closed doors. It’s clear that Varoufakis’ effectiveness in the second job was sacrificed to his devotion to the first, but it would have been just as bad—worse even—if he had sacrificed the first to the second.
The two jobs are so contradictory in their demands that it makes sense to divide them between two people. Varoufakis’ knowledge of economics and intense absorption in it is a benefit to his public role but gets in the way of being the kind of negotiating partner the creditors are looking for. Let Varoufakis bike around Europe drumming up support for Greece, and have a publicity-shy technician parse the negotiating texts.
Of course, rearranging the personalities on the negotiating team can only go so far. If the creditors are unwilling to bend on pensions, for instance, and neither is Syriza, even the chummiest personal relations between the parties is not going to be enough.
Second, as finance minister, Varoufakis was the point person in negotiations with peers from the other countries. Diplomatic etiquette, again rightly or wrongly, requires a limited public presence and clubby, consensus-building behavior behind closed doors. It’s clear that Varoufakis’ effectiveness in the second job was sacrificed to his devotion to the first, but it would have been just as bad—worse even—if he had sacrificed the first to the second.
The two jobs are so contradictory in their demands that it makes sense to divide them between two people. Varoufakis’ knowledge of economics and intense absorption in it is a benefit to his public role but gets in the way of being the kind of negotiating partner the creditors are looking for. Let Varoufakis bike around Europe drumming up support for Greece, and have a publicity-shy technician parse the negotiating texts.
Of course, rearranging the personalities on the negotiating team can only go so far. If the creditors are unwilling to bend on pensions, for instance, and neither is Syriza, even the chummiest personal relations between the parties is not going to be enough.
Subscribe to:
Posts (Atom)