Thursday, February 9, 2012
The Infamous Example of Rent Control in Introductory Economics
The latest post by Jodie Beggs rehashing the standard story about rent control has me quietly steaming. It’s not her fault, of course: she is simply regurgitating what has become a mandatory morality tale, an unavoidable rite of passage in Econ 101. You know the drill: in their misguided desire to be fair to the poor, the authorities have set a ceiling on rents below the market-clearing price, and the result is excess demand in the short run and reduced supply in the long run. Now that you have mastered the supply and demand diagram, you are so much smarter than they are.
I’m agnostic about rent control myself (it depends entirely on the context and the details), but for me this story is a poster child for the ideological rigidity of economics as it is taught to impressionable youth, not the superiority of “the economic way of thinking”.
There are two huge holes in the textbook argument. The first is that it overlooks neighborhood effects—literally. The most compelling argument for rent control is neighborhood stabilization, the idea that social capital in an urban environment requires stable residence patterns. If prices are volatile, and this leads to a lot of residential turnover, the result can be a less desirable neighborhood for everyone. Thus the quality-adjusted supply curve is partly a function of price (or at least price stability in a dynamic model), and the S and D curves are not independent of each other. You’ll notice that not a single textbook treatment of rent control mentions stabilization as an objective, even though this is a standard element in the real-world rhetoric surrounding this issue. Again, I’m not taking a position, just saying that the representation you get at the introductory level is an ideological construct, not an honest analysis.
The second hole is that rent control ordinances are normally replete with measures intended to maintain supply incentives, like price increases tied to investment in housing quality or simply spreading out increases over a longer time so tenants are able to adjust. Again, these measures may succeed or fail, but a simple horizontal line in a one-period S&D model doesn’t begin to address them.
In fact, advocates for rent control have taken Econ 101 (most of them), but they just disagree on how large the positive and negative impacts are. The purpose of economics should be to help us think clearly about the matter—for instance by identifying the potential empirical data that could adjudicate between competing arguments—but in its textbook form it is a ritualistic way of curtailing thought.
UPDATE: Standing in the shower, my mind drifted back to Orwell: "Free markets good! Price controls b-a-a-a-a-d!"
Wednesday, February 8, 2012
T-SPLOST: Financing Georgia’s Transportation Projects and Ricardian Equivalence
If voters approve a new one-cent sales tax for transportation projects, it could be one of the greatest economic tools in Georgia, according to an official pitching the benefits of the proposal. “This is the best option on the table. Is it perfect? No. Is it the best thing going? Absolutely,” said Doug Callaway, executive director of the Georgia Transportation Alliance — a nonprofit group affiliated with the Georgia Chamber of Commerce. Come July 31, voters in 12 districts throughout the state will be asked to consider a 10-year, one-cent sales tax that will fund transportation projects in their region … Callaway outlined the key points of the T-SPLOST that voters will likely hear until they head to the polls this summer: More jobs, safer roads and revenue that stays in the region. “We’ve got high unemployment, let’s be honest, and little hope for an immediate turnaround,” Callaway said, while pointing to University of Georgia experts who estimate that the economy won’t improve until 2020.Those regions that approve the T-SPLOST stand to possibly create more immediate and long-term jobs — while recovering more quickly from the economic downturn, he explained.
T-SPLOST stands for the Transportation Special Local Option Sales Tax. If a county decides to increase its sales tax by 1% for each of the next 10 years, then construction on new transportation projects can begin. Mr. Callaway is justifying this proposal on Keynesian grounds. While I hope Georgia’s economy can recovery before 2020, we have to admit the current recovery is going slowly.
Not to dust off an old debate, but let’s recall what Robert Lucas once argued:
But, if we do build the bridge by taking tax money away from somebody else, and using that to pay the bridge builder -- the guys who work on the bridge -- then it's just a wash. It has no first-starter effect. There's no reason to expect any stimulation. And, in some sense, there's nothing to apply a multiplier to. (Laughs.) You apply a multiplier to the bridge builders, then you've got to apply the same multiplier with a minus sign to the people you taxed to build the bridge. And then taxing them later isn't going to help, we know that.
Several economists challenged Dr. Lucas including this from Simon Wren-Lewis:
If you spend X at time t to build a bridge, aggregate demand increases by X at time t. If you raise taxes by X at time t, consumers will smooth this effect over time, so their spending at time t will fall by much less than X. Put the two together and aggregate demand rises.
If Mr. Callaway has his way, maybe we can have an empirical test along the lines that Christina Romer talked about!
Tuesday, February 7, 2012
A Generally Positive Jolt
BLS just released its preliminary December figure for job openings (from its Job Openings and Labor Turnover Survey—JOLTS), and the news is good: 258,000 more vacancies. Combined with previously reported unemployment data, the unemployment to vacancy ratio dipped noticeably from 4.3 to 3.9. Here is how the ratio looks from the beginning of 2008 to the end of 2011:
Newt’s Objection to Romney’s Minimum Wage Proposal – Does Newt Know Alan Krueger and David Card?
And Newt Gingrich, Romney's leading rival for the nomination, said Sunday on Meet the Press that "virtually every economist in the country believes that [indexing the minimum wage to inflation] further makes it difficult for young people to get a job."
This story next reminds us of a study written by Alan Krueger and David Card, which challenged Newt’s ideology.
Ten Minutes to Grok the Eurocrisis
Monday, February 6, 2012
Charles Murray’s Daring Move
Murray has a new book out, Coming Apart: The State of White America, 1960-2010, that argues that the top fifth of the (white) income distribution excels on merit and virtue, while the bottom 30% is mired in a dysfunctional, dead-end culture. Thus the income divide is just a symptom of the real cause, the widening virtue gap.
It takes guts to go out on a limb like this, doesn’t it? Imagine trying to convince the upper middle class that they are morally superior: do you think he will be able to drum up any sales?
Towards an economic theory of capitalism - MACRO supply and demand
This afternoon I discovered an interesting publication on the web entitled 'Tragedy and Hope - A History of the World in our Time'. It was published in 1966 by professor Carrol Quigley (an American historian and theorist of the evolution of civilizations) who taught at Georgetown University in the US in the 1960s and is reported to be a mentor for former US President Bill Clinton.
Within the pages of 'Tragedy and Hope' Quigley has articulated an essential aspect of the behaviour of money versus goods between geographical areas in the capitalist context:
“Capitalism, because it seems profits as its primary goal, is never primarily seeking to achieve prosperity, high production, high consumption, political power, patriotic improvement, or moral uplift. Goods moved from low-price areas to high-price areas and money moved from high-price areas to low-price areas because goods were more valuable where prices were high and money was more valuable where prices were low. Thus, clearly, money and goods are not the same thing but are, on the contrary, exactly opposite things. Most confusion in economic thinking arises from failure to recognize this fact. Goods are wealth which you have, while money is a claim on wealth which you do not have. Thus goods are an asset; money is a debt. If goods are wealth; money is non-wealth, or negative wealth, or even anti-wealth.”[*]
In these times the truth of the above statement appears obvious. Cheap goods are definitely moving from low-priced areas in China and South East Asia (in particular) to fully-industrialised nations where they fetch a much higher price. Money, in the form of capital, has been flowing out of the rich western nations and moving to the 'low-priced areas' around the globe.
The trouble is, that although Quigley's theory has the strong ring of truth to it, his theory contradicts the basic micro-economic theory of supply and demand. Foundational economic teachings have made it clear that it is the demand for individual goods that are impacted by price level, and that the price level is (largely) set by the level of consumer demand. However, Quigley writes about a wide range of goods in a particular geographic areas and not about any particular good.
I assume, therefore, that Quigley is implying that international currency manipulation is a key part of the operations of the world capitalist system. A low value for domestic currency makes goods (and services) cheaper for international buyers, and vice versa.
Capitalism's foundation therefore must rely on processes of unequal exchange where the 'price mechanism' for goods is largely determined by the relative value of the currency they are purchased in.
"It is quite impossible to understand the history of the twentieth century without some understanding of the role played by money in domestic affairs and in foreign affairs, as well as the role played by bankers in economic life and in political life" is Quigley's understatement.
Deregulation did not turn out to be 'no regulation' after all. It appears to have simply meant leaving the management of the world economy largely to the whims of a global and organised cartel of private banks (ie the central banks).
"The power of the State must be invoked for restoring economic freedom just as it has been invoked for destroying economic freedom."
Hilaire Belloc, The Restoration of Property, 1936
REFERENCES:
Quigley ‘Tragedy and Hope’ 1966. http://sandiego.indymedia.org/media/2006/10/119975.pdf
Also see:
Finance leaders fail to resolve currency dispute
Martin Crutsinger, Saturday, October 9, 2010, Associated Press
http://www.activistpost.com/2010/10/finance-leaders-fail-to-resolve.htmlForest Conservation and the Rise of the 1%
Over here we have debate on the decades-long upsurge in inequality, fueled by the increasing share of income going to the top 1%. Over there we have the politics of forest prevention, specifically the push by the state of Colorado to weaken roadless protection in order, among other things, to try to suppress forest fires. What’s the connection?
The main purpose of the roadless areas directive is to keep land available for wilderness designation. The guiding philosophy of wilderness is that large swaths of forest, desert and other ecosystems need to be left alone to provide the sort of habitat, recreation and research that can exist only in the absence of large-scale human interference. Keeping out roads is a way of putting a ceiling on that interference.
One aspect of wilderness is permitting a natural fire ecology. Periodic fires are part of the system, so they should be allowed to burn off excess fuel and permit the rotation of tree species. (Fire-resistant species thrive in the wake of a fire but are eventually displaced by more susceptible competitors, until another fire begins the cycle again.) The expectation has been that more of these smaller fires will reduce the number of monster burns.
It hasn’t worked out quite that way. One reason is climate change, which is slowly redrawing the ecological map of North America. Some land that used to be forest is destined to be savannah or even drier, and fire, abetted by disease, is often the agent of change.
But something else has happened, much more rapidly: large numbers of the newly rich have chosen to build their second (or nth) homes in remote areas of Colorado, Wyoming, Montana and other mountain states. They like the magnificent vistas and opportunities for recreation provided by public lands, as long as they can own their own private chunk next door. Naturally, they have the means to fly back and forth, so distance is not a problem .
What is a problem is fire. Even the small fires envisioned in wilderness philosophy threaten their lovely dachas. In remarkably bloodless language, the Times summed up this dynamic:
But he [Glenn Casamassa, a US Forest Service supervisor] said the West, and maybe Colorado in particular, has also changed significantly in the intervening years. More people are living near national forests. An outbreak of pine-killing bark beetles that has its epicenter in Colorado and several major fires over those years that roared out to touch the edge of urban life have also changed thinking about intervention in the wild.And that’s how it is. If a proposed financial regulation runs afoul of the 1%, out it goes. If closing a tax loophole brings their rate up to everyone else’s, no go. And if wilderness gets in the way of their weekend getaways, then this requires “changed thinking” among forest managers.
Plutocracy does have consequences.
Sunday, February 5, 2012
Would President Gingrich Hire Christina Romer as Economic Advisor?
The one thing that has disillusioned me is the discussion of fiscal policy. Policymakers and far too many economists seem to be arguing from ideology rather than evidence. As I have described this evening, the evidence is stronger than it has ever been that fiscal policy matters—that fiscal stimulus helps the economy add jobs, and that reducing the budget deficit lowers growth at least in the near term. And yet, this evidence does not seem to be getting through to the legislative process. That is unacceptable. We are never going to solve our problems if we can’t agree at least on the facts. Evidence-based policymaking is essential if we are ever going to triumph over this recession and deal with our long-run budget problems.
Gingrich isn’t exactly known for seeking reality based advice, which is why this stunned me:
Newt Gingrich said Sunday that an “age of austerity” is the wrong solution for the economy and would “punish” the American people. He said he prefers “pro-growth” policies instead. The comments appear to pour cold water on the modern Republican belief that austerity and growth go hand in hand.
I just wish we could take the latest from Newt seriously!
Friday, February 3, 2012
The Chinese Question: Liquidity or Solvency?
Once again the EU is trying to get China to commit a few hundred billion of its foreign exchange reserves to shoring up Eurozone sovereign debt. The European “stability” mechanisms (EFSM and ESM) need more money, and no one in Europe is willing to lay that much on the line. China says it would be willing to step in, but under one condition: that its investments are guaranteed.
This is perfectly reasonable. China is still a largely poor country, and there is no reason why its people should risk losing their savings in order to help manage the affairs of much wealthier Europe. At the same time, however, their demand exposes the fundamental dishonesty of Eurozone policy.
Except for Greece, the official line is that all sovereign debts will be honored and all fiscal targets met. The rescue facilities exist only to provide bridge loans that markets are unwilling to extend at a reasonable cost. With enough liquidity, austerity and reform, financial sustainability is assured.
If this were really the case, however, there would be little risk in giving the Chinese the guarantee they demand. And no one seriously expects such a guarantee to be offered.
The reason is that the true situation in the Eurozone bears little relation to the optimistic talk still issuing from summits like the one just concluded in Brussels. Greece is only the first in line; Portugal too will need debt relief and perhaps also Ireland. Spain faces an entire banking system that may well be technically insolvent, and it can neither survive a banking collapse nor come up with the funds to forestall one. All the severely indebted countries are at risk from the gathering recession, and the need for further recapitalization of the banks across the continent is a further risk.
In the face of this frightening public and private debt overhang, the official policy has been to lend, lend and lend some more. The ECB has turned back the doomsday clock by lending half a trillion or so euros at close to zero interest to private banks in return for their own lending to overstretched sovereigns. So-called bailouts, like the next tranche at issue in Greece, are also loans. Politicians give stern speeches about how debt cannot be the solution to debt, and then they find more spigots for lending: beef up the European Financial Stability Mechanism, bring on a permanent mechanism, go door to door in China.
But if the problem is not liquidity but solvency, this avalanche of credit is profoundly wrongheaded. The solution for insolvency is always the same: write down existing unpayable debts and generate income—transfers if necessary—to forestall new debts. In the current environment each is associated with an immense political-economic challenge, since the first requires confronting the European financial oligarchy and the second creating a true, zone-wide fiscal entity (the feared transfer union). Achieving either alone would be a miracle; accomplishing both is almost beyond utopia.
At least we can thank the Chinese for clarifying the contradiction at the heart of the current policy charade.
Thursday, February 2, 2012
What happens when monetary values replace notions of real wealth? Quotes from 2011
“The Fed can’t print oil.” [1]
"What’s most terrifying, we are having this discussion about the risk of recession at a time when unemployment is already too high, at a time when a quarter of homeowners are underwater on their mortgages, at a time then the fiscal deficit is at 9 percent and at a time when interest rates are at zero." [2]
“We’re on the verge of a great, great depression. The [Federal Reserve] knows it” [3]
Since China entered the WTO in 2001, the U.S. trade deficit with China has grown by an average of 18% per year. The U.S. trade deficit with China in 2010 was 27 times larger than it was back in 1990. The United States has lost an average of 50,000 manufacturing jobs per month since China joined the World Trade Organization in 2001. [4]
244 Members of Congress Flunked Arithmetic
Every House Republican voted Thursday to reject the proposition that the Bush tax cuts added to the deficit. Joined by just a handful of Democrats, the full Republican conference rejected a measure that would have affirmed what nearly all budget experts and economists recognized: President George W. Bush's debt-financed tax cuts blew up the budget in the last decade, leaving the country in a hole that sank into a chasm after the 2008 financial crisis. The final tally was 174-244.
I guess their next vote will declare that the Earth is flat.
Wednesday, February 1, 2012
A Curious Case of Plagiarism... and of Contradiction
BUT the positive side to this dumb paper is the sentence, "Those who make the fallacy claim fail to offer specific evidence of the supposed belief in a fixed amount of work." That's a paraphrase of what the Sandwichman has been saying for 10 years!Well the Sandwichman was wrong.
How Would Romney Pay for the Repairs in the Safety Net?
“I’m not concerned about the very poor, we have a safety net there,” Romney said. “If it needs repair, I’ll fix it. I’m not concerned about the very rich, they’re doing just fine. I’m concerned about the very heart of America, the 90, 95 percent of Americans who, right now, are struggling, and I’ll continue to take that message across the nation.”
I guess some Democratic hacks could take the very first part of this statement out of context (Romney is not concerned about the very poor) but let’s do as he lectured Soledad O’Brien and finish the sentence. The safety net does need repair and that would involve an increase in government spending. Now if Mr. Romney has decided to agree with President Obama about the very rich doing fine, then have him say we will pay for this increase in government spending by raising taxes on the very rich. But wait – his tax proposal would dramatically reduce Federal revenues by giving the very rich even more tax breaks. So the arithmetic just does not add up unless Mr. Romney is proposing even bigger deficits. Of course, this kind of doubletalk is where Mitt Romney excels.
≡
It’s amazing, isn’t it, that professional economists could argue about the relationship of identity and equilibrium and fail to come to a quick agreement? I see that David Glasner and Scott Sumner are still having at each other over at Uneasy Money. And I am truly baffled by Glasner’s claim “that it is incoherent to state that the income-expenditure model of national income requires savings to equal investment whether or not equilibrium obtains...”
It’s all rather easy: an accounting identity imposes a necessary relationship between a set a variables on the basis of their definition, but it doesn’t say what the value of any particular variable will be. Behavioral arguments, which may employ the concept of equilibrium (but don’t have to), attempt to explain or predict these values. A behavioral argument may be right or wrong—people may behave the way you say they do, nor not—but an identity is an identity is an identity.
I disagree strongly with Noah Smith and Paul Krugman, however on the question of whether one can learn anything substantive from identities; clearly the answer is yes. Rather than make a theoretical argument, I will link to a chapter from my introductory macroeconomics text. It is all about identity---there is no discussion at all about equilibrium—but I think students would learn a number of useful things about national and global economic patterns from reading it. See if you agree.
And the next time you accuse someone of not fully comprehending an identity, look in the mirror.