Do you know Hume's argument for an Established Church? It is quoted in Smith's Wealth of Nations and it is too good not to share. It is Hume at his most impish.
Hume notes that diligence on the part of a worker of any sort depends on, as we would now say, his pay varying with performance. A flat wage not tied to performance leads to an “indolent” worker. An established religion where the clergy are paid a fixed salary by the state will then produce an indolent clergy. And this, for Hume, is a good reason for state establishment, since “this interested diligence of the clergy is what every wise legislator will study to prevent”!
The result of free competition among clergy whose pay depends on the extent and devotion of their congregation, by contrast, will be that:“each ghostly practitioner, in order to render himself more precious and sacred in the eyes of retainers, will inspire them with the most violent abhorrence of all other sects...no regard will be paid to truth, morals or decency in the doctrines cultivated. Every tenet will be adopted that best suits the disorderly affections of the human frame. Customers will be drawn to each conventicle
by new industry and address in practicing on the passions and credulity of the populace.”
Thursday, June 21, 2012
Wednesday, June 20, 2012
Will A Thousand CEOs Save The Planet? Report From Rio
Just back from presenting paper at International Society for Ecological Economics (ISEE) conference in Rio that preceded the main UN Sustainable Development conference that has started today there, the Rio + 20 show. What is going on there is much more than the UN part, which will probably amount to a lot of fine resolutions signifying very little. Demos are going on; we saw a bunch of landless marching, an "Occupa" group in tents protesting an arrest in Uruguay, and in the local paper feminists marching topless and a fancily made up Indian blocking traffic with his bow and arrow.
But the real show is all the other stuff, not just ISEE, but 500 side conferences. I saw a claim that 60,000 people are in Rio for all this, with 1000 of those being CEOs, yes, CEOs. Indeed, in our hotel I saw all kinds of business people, all dressed up and going to conferences. The weirdest were Russian oil men from Siberia. Now that has got to lead to green capitalism! Another guy in a suit was attending a list of alphabet soup I did not recognize, although he did say he works for International Business Phones, whoever they are. Saw a sign for something called ISGIE (could not track down on google who they are), but they were all in suits, and there was a big sign welcoming the Thai delegation for that one. Indeed, for the main event, supposedly there are reps from over 130 countries.
I suspect the vast majority of these are wannabe rent seekers, out to get government subsidies for this that or the other thing. I do not know. Many I am sure have little real interest in improving the environment (see Russian oil men above). OTOH, it does occur to me that when the green movement gets real, it is when one really gets business people doing stuff about it and making money from it. Will any of those there seeking to make money out of all this actually accomplish anything worthwhile? I really do not know. I suspect the vast majority will not, but maybe some of them actually will, and I suspect that they will be the participants there not making any headlines.
As for ISEE, it is an uber green outfit also notable for taking heterodox positions regarding economic analysis, at least its founders and leaders. One of the plenary speakers was the Prime Minister of Bhutan, the place where they first started saying they want to emphasize happiness over GDP. Some of the papers and sessions were simply awful, the sort of thing that I suspect is going on at many other of the 500 side events (and maybe the main one as well), people going on about meta-analysis of how to implement the format for assessing how to discuss sustainability. I am not kidding.
But then there were papers on very specific things going on in very specific places that gave me some hope, such as the efforts to provide credits for reforestation in developing countries through the Reducing Emissions from Deforestation and Desertification (REDD) UN project. Unsurprisingly the bottom line often gets down to details. Seems to be working in Kenya, mixed bag in Senegal (depends on which trees are planted), not doing so well in Nicaragua because central government grabs 3/4 of the credits, and in West Bengal the better off peasants in upper castes are doing much better out of the program than the poorer scheduled castes and scheduled tribal groups. Messy reality out there, but worthwhile things are actually happening on the ground in some places, even if Nature journal is right that overall humanity deserves Fs on climate change, biodiversity, and income inequality since the last Rio conference 20 years ago.
But the real show is all the other stuff, not just ISEE, but 500 side conferences. I saw a claim that 60,000 people are in Rio for all this, with 1000 of those being CEOs, yes, CEOs. Indeed, in our hotel I saw all kinds of business people, all dressed up and going to conferences. The weirdest were Russian oil men from Siberia. Now that has got to lead to green capitalism! Another guy in a suit was attending a list of alphabet soup I did not recognize, although he did say he works for International Business Phones, whoever they are. Saw a sign for something called ISGIE (could not track down on google who they are), but they were all in suits, and there was a big sign welcoming the Thai delegation for that one. Indeed, for the main event, supposedly there are reps from over 130 countries.
I suspect the vast majority of these are wannabe rent seekers, out to get government subsidies for this that or the other thing. I do not know. Many I am sure have little real interest in improving the environment (see Russian oil men above). OTOH, it does occur to me that when the green movement gets real, it is when one really gets business people doing stuff about it and making money from it. Will any of those there seeking to make money out of all this actually accomplish anything worthwhile? I really do not know. I suspect the vast majority will not, but maybe some of them actually will, and I suspect that they will be the participants there not making any headlines.
As for ISEE, it is an uber green outfit also notable for taking heterodox positions regarding economic analysis, at least its founders and leaders. One of the plenary speakers was the Prime Minister of Bhutan, the place where they first started saying they want to emphasize happiness over GDP. Some of the papers and sessions were simply awful, the sort of thing that I suspect is going on at many other of the 500 side events (and maybe the main one as well), people going on about meta-analysis of how to implement the format for assessing how to discuss sustainability. I am not kidding.
But then there were papers on very specific things going on in very specific places that gave me some hope, such as the efforts to provide credits for reforestation in developing countries through the Reducing Emissions from Deforestation and Desertification (REDD) UN project. Unsurprisingly the bottom line often gets down to details. Seems to be working in Kenya, mixed bag in Senegal (depends on which trees are planted), not doing so well in Nicaragua because central government grabs 3/4 of the credits, and in West Bengal the better off peasants in upper castes are doing much better out of the program than the poorer scheduled castes and scheduled tribal groups. Messy reality out there, but worthwhile things are actually happening on the ground in some places, even if Nature journal is right that overall humanity deserves Fs on climate change, biodiversity, and income inequality since the last Rio conference 20 years ago.
Blurbs for Economic Classics That Might Have Been
Hayek, The Foetal Conceit
The book asks whether life begins at Concepcion and answers that if you are Chilean or Paraguayan, it very well may have!
Veblen, Theory of The Business Class
This curmudgeon knows his air travel like nobody's business!
Smith, The Wealth of Martians
18th Century Science Fiction at its very best!
Mankiw, Mackereleconomics
The definitive text for natural resource economics.
The book asks whether life begins at Concepcion and answers that if you are Chilean or Paraguayan, it very well may have!
Veblen, Theory of The Business Class
This curmudgeon knows his air travel like nobody's business!
Smith, The Wealth of Martians
18th Century Science Fiction at its very best!
Mankiw, Mackereleconomics
The definitive text for natural resource economics.
Tuesday, June 19, 2012
Eurozone crisis originated in North America
"This crisis was not originated in Europe … seeing as you mention North America, this crisis originated in North America and much of our financial sector was contaminated by, how can I put it, unorthodox practices, from some sectors of the financial market." José Manuel Barroso at the G20 summit in Mexico, 19th June 2012Well, how did $34 trillion dollars suddenly appear in global capital markets between 2000 and 2007?
Monday, June 18, 2012
The globalisation crisis – looking at Greece
Greece’s elections are now over with the winners vowing to
stay in the Eurozone and thus stabilizing global financial markets in the short
term. No one believes the crisis is over
in Europe, however.
Greece’s four biggest banks have recently received an 18
billion-euro injection of funds “but may need a lot more” [1].
In Greece, as it is around the globe today, private banks possess
superior status and receive preference over ordinary private companies. A moral
hazard of always being saved by governments has set in for the larger financial
entities. Governments then present the
bank bailout bill to their taxpaying citizens. The obvious question is why are they not
allowed to simply fail? Why aren’t these
private institutions being nationalized? But these questions seem never to be explored
in current mainstream media coverage.
Isn’t it clear that the problem in Greece is that of
globalization itself? Financial
institutions operating in individual nations are now a part of a much larger global
network. Therefore any process of
nationalization and any measures to limit the mobility of capital (to avoid
dangerous and unpredictable capital flight) go completely counter to the
interests of the world’s financial actors – not
just those of Europe and Greece.
We can see now that the predictable and catastrophic results
of passing on these enormous bailout costs to the general public are playing
out. Business is simply not managing in Greece. With 400 - 425 million Euros a
day disappearing from Greece’s banks (during the last 2 weeks) even healthy
business units in Greece cannot guarantee their working capital. Any goods being brought into Greece have to
be prepaid for.
Solutions are being proposed such as implementing ‘the right
tax policy’ and even further deregulation for business and the general
reduction of ‘bureaucracy’. [2] Solutions that don’t address the actual cause
of the crisis are very unlikely to work.
Greece is also left vulnerable because it is no longer a ‘production-based
economy’. 48% of Greece’s food comes
from elsewhere for instance. Who will
guarantee continued supply if Greece’s financial credentials are destroyed?
It’s been a long time of not thinking about the wrongness of
abandoning many local methods of resilience and productivity. As Thomas Paine noted in the late 18th
Century [3] the longer the social habit
of not thinking about a wrong “gives
it a superficial appearance of being right.”
Time, rather than reason, has made many of us converts to the ideology
of globalization. Formerly prosperous
middle class families in Greece go hungry tonight while they finally have more time to
ponder on the validity of ancient strategies for basic survival.
REFERENCES:
[1] Bailout of Greek
banks is good, but not enough
02/06/2012
With an 18 billion-euro bailout, Greek banks are now staying
afloat. But losses and political instability could easily sink the ship.
By Andy Dabilis for Southeast European Times in Athens --
02/06/12
[2] Lateline, ABC
TV. Monday 18th June 2012.
11:25pm
[3] Thomas Paine,
Common Sense (1776)
Sunday, June 17, 2012
Niall Ferguson Exposes Two Problems with Balanced Budget Amendments
Niall Ferguson intended to make the case for austerity measures including a balanced budget amendment. Dean Baker read this before going to bed last night and started the critique of this tiresome BBC op-ed:
Hmmmm, $200 trillion at the federal level and $38 trillion at the state and local level? Can we get a source for this? Is there a date there for when the Martians will attack Planet Earth? In fairness, there are nutty projections that assume that per capita health care costs in the United States will be four or five times as high as in all other wealthy countries. If this proves true, over an infinite horizon we will have a very bad deficit problem. Of course, these health care costs would wreck our economy regardless of what we do with public sector health care programs. These projections would cause serious people to talk about the need to fix the health care system. But this is national economic policy that we are talking about. But this piece suggests an easy route for dealing with the deficit. Clearly there is a big market for deficit hawks.Dean’s clever solution would be to spend money training college grads to write more gibberish like what the BBC should published. This would employ resources currently being left idle and hopefully generate more tax revenue via the traditional Keynesian mechanisms. Niall, however, suggests we pass a balanced budget amendment (which BTW does not tell us which tax rates we need to raise or which expenditures we need to reduce). As he does so, he does note:
The trouble is that the experience of the financial crisis has substantially strengthened the case for using the government deficit as a tool to stimulate the economy in times of recession.Well – yea! Isn’t that the classic problem with balanced budget amendments – they turn fiscal policy into a pro-cyclical disaster. But let’s move onto the other problem by quoting Neill:
The present system is, to put it bluntly, fraudulent. There are no regularly published and accurate official balance sheets. Huge liabilities are simply hidden from view. Not even the current income and expenditure statements can be relied upon in some countries. No legitimate business could possible carry on in this fashion.In other words, the way we normally measure deficits – current spending minus current taxes – does not capture those allegedly large present value shortfalls. Here is where Dean’s call for a course and his quip about the date that the Martians will attack Earth comes in. Niall’s alleged $238 trillion shortfall relies on some discounted cash flow calculation that he doesn’t even specify. What is the discount rate? What are projected expenditures over an infinite horizon? What are projected taxes over an infinite horizon? Such calculations require a host of assumptions. We are supposed to put all of this into a Constitutional Amendment?
Saturday, June 16, 2012
The Cost of Volcker’s Disinflation and 1978-Era Macroeconomics

And one of the things they tend to bring up is the hoary old myth that the 80s success in taming inflation was somehow a terrible shock and surprise to Keynesians, who had no explanation. This is, as it happens, completely wrong: what actually happened in the 80s was, quite literally, a confirmation of the validity of textbook Keynesian economics. OK, first the facts: the 80s were marked first by a simultaneous surge in unemployment and plunge in inflation. Then unemployment came down but inflation stayed low(ish) … Inflation rate = -α(u – NAIRU) + Lagged inflation rate where u was the unemployment rate and the NAIRU was the non-accelerating-inflation rate of unemployment. And what did this approach predict about disinflation? It said that if policy makers were willing to impose a period of very high unemployment, they could bring inflation down — and that even if unemployment then fell back to the NAIRU, inflation would stay down.Paul’s graph shows the unemployment rate over the 1979 to 1988, while our graph shows the GDP gap (using the CBO definition of potential GDP) over the same period. Notice we had a sizeable gap during the last two years of the Carter Administration followed by an enormous gap right after Reagan took office. The gap narrowed over the next few years but was still around 1 percent of GDP as Reagan’s second term started. Much of the movement in the GDP gap both up and down should be attributed to Volcker’s monetary policy. I agree with Paul’s assertion that it required a sustained period of often significant excess supply to achieve this disinflation. Some critics of this view, however, note how quickly inflation fell during the second bout of Volcker’s tight monetary policy (1982 recession). Gordon’s paper, however, also includes the following:
Instead this paper revives the supply‐side invented in the mid‐1970s that recognizes the co‐existence of flexible auction‐market prices for commodities like oil and sticky prices for the remaining non‐oil economy. Adverse supply shocks coming not just from oil prices but also, as in the early 1970s from auction‐market price shocks in food and exchange rates, boosted the expenditure share of commodities and forced nominal spending on non‐shocked products to contract.Adverse supply shocks were partially for the run-up in inflation that the Volcker FED inherited. I would add that the U.S. economy had a series of favorable supply shocks, which were part of the reason why inflation fell so quickly. The oil price hikes during OPEC II were partially offset by oil price decreases while the dollar appreciation (due to the tug of war between Reagan’s fiscal stimulus and Volcker’s second bout of monetary contraction) lowered the dollar price of imports. This dollar appreciation had to later be reversed, which is why inflation stopped declining even as the GDP gap remained positive. Viewed over the entire 1979 to 1988 period, we did have to endure an awful lot of cumulative pain to get the inflation rate down to the lower levels enjoyed during the Great Moderation.
Thursday, June 14, 2012
First Stab at a New Book: The Matrix: The Conjunction of War, Economic Theory, and the Economy
Vincent Portillo, a colleague, will join me in putting a new book
together. We only have 10 paragraphs to show for our effort, but any
comments will be very much appreciated. Getting an introduction down
is important, not only for communicating with readers, but for sorting
out our own ideas. Thanks.
This book is an exploration of the complex and fascinating
interactions between war, the economy, and economic thinking. Whether
you realize it or not, a complex Matrix resulting from the
interactions of war, economics, and economic thinking creates a
powerful force field that affects almost everything you do. This
force field, not unlike gravity, is both pervasive and invisible.
However, the effects of the Matrix are unpredictable. In a world
vulnerable to the possibility of serious destruction as the result of
both military and economic miscalculations, taking account of this
Matrix is imperative.
The effects of the Matrix are far more complex than those of gravity.
Obviously, an engineer designing an airplane must take into account
the force of gravity to avoid future calamities. Complete command of
the necessary scientific knowledge and care in the building of the
plane is insufficient to guarantee future safety. The human interface
creates an ever-present risk once pilots, mechanics, and air traffic
controllers take over responsibilities for the plane.
A far more intricate network of human behaviors interacting with the
Matrix leads to pervasive uncertainty, making the challenges of
responding to the Matrix are far more daunting than the
straightforward responsibilities of those who are responsible for the
plane's safety. The Matrix presents another dimension of
complications. If a pilot flies into a mountain, the immediacy of the
consequences makes interpretation of the event fairly simple.
In the case of the Matrix, choices today may set off a chain of events
that may have important consequences years or decades in the future.
Looking back to identify a single -- or even a small set of events as
the cause is very difficult. After all, events occurring in previous
millennia still remain the subject of ongoing debates among
historians. To make matters even more complex, the Matrix can cause
contradictory outcomes.
Here again, the human element comes into play. Any attempt at
identifying causality comes up again the tendency to understand the
sequence of events in light of pre-existing ideas or ideology.
Consequently, one must exercise extreme caution in any attempt to
manipulate the Matrix. Nonetheless, the risks of doing nothing are
even more dangerous, considering the potential dangers or perhaps even
likelihood of environmental, economic, or military disaster. Actions
to prevent cataclysmic outcomes require great care, backed up with a
relatively holistic perspective.
Economics occupies a special place in this intricate Matrix with
economics serving as a bridge between the other two principals of the
Matrix: war and the economy. Almost unintentionally, in the
seventeenth century, modern economics developed to a large extent in
response to questions raised by the needs and the consequences of
warfare.
More at
http://michaelperelman.wordpress.com/2012/06/15/first-stab-at-a-new-book-the-matrix-the-conjunction-of-war-economic-theory-and-the-economy/
together. We only have 10 paragraphs to show for our effort, but any
comments will be very much appreciated. Getting an introduction down
is important, not only for communicating with readers, but for sorting
out our own ideas. Thanks.
This book is an exploration of the complex and fascinating
interactions between war, the economy, and economic thinking. Whether
you realize it or not, a complex Matrix resulting from the
interactions of war, economics, and economic thinking creates a
powerful force field that affects almost everything you do. This
force field, not unlike gravity, is both pervasive and invisible.
However, the effects of the Matrix are unpredictable. In a world
vulnerable to the possibility of serious destruction as the result of
both military and economic miscalculations, taking account of this
Matrix is imperative.
The effects of the Matrix are far more complex than those of gravity.
Obviously, an engineer designing an airplane must take into account
the force of gravity to avoid future calamities. Complete command of
the necessary scientific knowledge and care in the building of the
plane is insufficient to guarantee future safety. The human interface
creates an ever-present risk once pilots, mechanics, and air traffic
controllers take over responsibilities for the plane.
A far more intricate network of human behaviors interacting with the
Matrix leads to pervasive uncertainty, making the challenges of
responding to the Matrix are far more daunting than the
straightforward responsibilities of those who are responsible for the
plane's safety. The Matrix presents another dimension of
complications. If a pilot flies into a mountain, the immediacy of the
consequences makes interpretation of the event fairly simple.
In the case of the Matrix, choices today may set off a chain of events
that may have important consequences years or decades in the future.
Looking back to identify a single -- or even a small set of events as
the cause is very difficult. After all, events occurring in previous
millennia still remain the subject of ongoing debates among
historians. To make matters even more complex, the Matrix can cause
contradictory outcomes.
Here again, the human element comes into play. Any attempt at
identifying causality comes up again the tendency to understand the
sequence of events in light of pre-existing ideas or ideology.
Consequently, one must exercise extreme caution in any attempt to
manipulate the Matrix. Nonetheless, the risks of doing nothing are
even more dangerous, considering the potential dangers or perhaps even
likelihood of environmental, economic, or military disaster. Actions
to prevent cataclysmic outcomes require great care, backed up with a
relatively holistic perspective.
Economics occupies a special place in this intricate Matrix with
economics serving as a bridge between the other two principals of the
Matrix: war and the economy. Almost unintentionally, in the
seventeenth century, modern economics developed to a large extent in
response to questions raised by the needs and the consequences of
warfare.
More at
http://michaelperelman.wordpress.com/2012/06/15/first-stab-at-a-new-book-the-matrix-the-conjunction-of-war-economic-theory-and-the-economy/
Equity Participation as an Alternative to Student Loans
Luigi Zingales is critical of government subsidized student loans:
Nearly eight million students received Pell grants in 2010, costing $28 billion. In addition, the federal direct loan program, which allows nonaffluent students to get government-guaranteed loans at low interest rates, cost taxpayers $13 billion in 2010-11. Total subsidies to university education amount to $43 billion a year, including around $2 billion in Congressional earmarks — and that does not even include tax subsidies (for college funds); tax breaks (for university endowments, for example); and subsidies dedicated to research. Just as subsidies for homeownership have increased the price of houses, so have education subsidies contributed to the soaring price of college. Between 1977 and 2009 the real average cost of university tuition more than doubled. These subsidies also distort the credit market. Since the government guarantees student loans, lenders have no incentive to lend wisely. All the burden of making the right decision falls on the borrowers. Unfortunately, 18-year-olds aren’t particularly good at judging the profitability of an investment without expert advice, and when they do get such advice, it generally counsels taking the largest possible loan. The stock of student loans has reached $1 trillion, while the percentage of borrowers in default jumped to 8.8 percent in 2009 from 6.7 percent in 2007. Last but not least, these subsidized loans keep afloat colleges that do not add much value for their students, preventing people from accumulating useful skills.He offers the following solution:
The best way to fix this inefficiency is to address the root of the problem: most bright students do not have any collateral and cannot easily pledge their future income. Yet the venture-capital industry has shown that the private sector can do a good job at financing new ventures with no collateral. So why can’t they finance bright students? Investors could finance students’ education with equity rather than debt. In exchange for their capital, the investors would receive a fraction of a student’s future income — or, even better, a fraction of the increase in her income that derives from college attendance.He correctly notes that this is akin to a system of voluntary taxation where the beneficiaries of a college education are the ones paying into the funding system. An interesting idea with the following caveat we often here from supply-side types. If the funding system were to receive a portion of one’s future income, would that be a disincentive for those “highly compensated superstars” to work as hard? Perhaps but it does seem to be a decent idea even if it does so as to bring greater opportunities to those who wish to pursue a college education on the hope of becoming a future superstar.
Tuesday, June 12, 2012
After 5 years, The Confiscation of American Prosperity is in Paperback
The young editor is enthusiastic about the sales after such a short period of availability.
Here is an Amazon ad, but it may be available locally.
http://www.amazon.com/The-Confiscation-American-Prosperity-Right-Wing/dp/1137009373/ref=sr_1_1?ie=UTF8&qid=1338911378&sr=8-1
Here is an Amazon ad, but it may be available locally.
http://www.amazon.com/The-Confiscation-American-Prosperity-Right-Wing/dp/1137009373/ref=sr_1_1?ie=UTF8&qid=1338911378&sr=8-1
RIP: Elinor Ostrom
I have just learned that Elinor Ostrom died this morning of cancer. The first woman to win the Nobel Prize in Economics (I know, I know, the Swedish Bank Prize, blah blah), she was officially a political scientist, and there were some who complained about her receiving the award because of that and because she had "never published in a top 5 economics journal," although she did so after receiving the prize. Also many fussed about not having heard of her, including people as prominent as Paul Krugman. As it is, her most famous work, her seminal 1990 book, Governing the Commons, has been cited more than 13,000 times, more alone than the entire citations received by more than half of the other economics Nobelists.
Although the basic insight had been made earlier, particularly by Siegfried von Ciriacy-Wantrup and his student, Richard Bishop in a 1975 paper in the fairly obscure Natural Resources Journal (now more or less run by lawyers), she was the one who really developed the point, working with multidisciplinary teams using a broad array of methods, including in-depth field studies, game theory, lab experiments, and a variety of other approaches, building up a massive institutional and historical knowledge and data base, she confirmed that the management system of a natural resource commons is what matters more than its official ownership. In a sense this is a rediscovery in a different context of the old ownership versus control argument that was initiated in the 1930s by Gardiner and Means, and was also a focus of the early behavioral economists as well who immediately followed Herbert Simon.
It remains the case even now in many textbooks that the issue is posed as "the tragedy of the commons," a phrase coined by Garret Hardin in the 1960s, with the idea being that there were two choices, either badly managed open access commons such as the encroached commons pastures of England, or private ownership of these resources. Ostrom and her associates argued that what mattered was the ability to control access, whatever the formal ownership scheme, and that privately owned properties that cannot control access, such as the homesteaded farmlands of the US Great Plains prior to the invention of barbed wire to keep the cattle out, were worse than many common properties that managed themselves. Much of this insight came from observing traditional management schemes of forests, and fisheriers, and irrigation systems, and pastures that worked, with the Alpine ones in Switzerland dating from the 1200s a classic example.
This ties with a broader story, that systems organized by the people who use the resources work better than ones imposed by outsiders. The classic case involves the forests of Nepal since WW II, a case emphasized by Ostrom. The forests ended up in basically three different kinds of systems. Some of them owned by corporations, influence from the British Raj, some of them were in state-owned and controlled systems from various socialist governments, and about a third remained in the hands of local groups managed in traditional ways. Today, most of the first two are gone, over-harvested and deforested. What is left of the forests of Nepal are those where the local traditional managers were able to keep on keeping on.
I can also attest that Lin Ostrom was a warm and engaging person, friendly to one and all and totally open-minded. She is a great loss to the broader intellectual and policy community of this world. May she rest in peace.
Although the basic insight had been made earlier, particularly by Siegfried von Ciriacy-Wantrup and his student, Richard Bishop in a 1975 paper in the fairly obscure Natural Resources Journal (now more or less run by lawyers), she was the one who really developed the point, working with multidisciplinary teams using a broad array of methods, including in-depth field studies, game theory, lab experiments, and a variety of other approaches, building up a massive institutional and historical knowledge and data base, she confirmed that the management system of a natural resource commons is what matters more than its official ownership. In a sense this is a rediscovery in a different context of the old ownership versus control argument that was initiated in the 1930s by Gardiner and Means, and was also a focus of the early behavioral economists as well who immediately followed Herbert Simon.
It remains the case even now in many textbooks that the issue is posed as "the tragedy of the commons," a phrase coined by Garret Hardin in the 1960s, with the idea being that there were two choices, either badly managed open access commons such as the encroached commons pastures of England, or private ownership of these resources. Ostrom and her associates argued that what mattered was the ability to control access, whatever the formal ownership scheme, and that privately owned properties that cannot control access, such as the homesteaded farmlands of the US Great Plains prior to the invention of barbed wire to keep the cattle out, were worse than many common properties that managed themselves. Much of this insight came from observing traditional management schemes of forests, and fisheriers, and irrigation systems, and pastures that worked, with the Alpine ones in Switzerland dating from the 1200s a classic example.
This ties with a broader story, that systems organized by the people who use the resources work better than ones imposed by outsiders. The classic case involves the forests of Nepal since WW II, a case emphasized by Ostrom. The forests ended up in basically three different kinds of systems. Some of them owned by corporations, influence from the British Raj, some of them were in state-owned and controlled systems from various socialist governments, and about a third remained in the hands of local groups managed in traditional ways. Today, most of the first two are gone, over-harvested and deforested. What is left of the forests of Nepal are those where the local traditional managers were able to keep on keeping on.
I can also attest that Lin Ostrom was a warm and engaging person, friendly to one and all and totally open-minded. She is a great loss to the broader intellectual and policy community of this world. May she rest in peace.
Does Romney Not Understand That States Face Balanced Budget Constraints?
How else can one explain this:
Mitt Romney finds the Obama campaign’s accusations that the public sector would lose jobs under his leadership “completely absurd,” he said on “Fox & Friends” Tuesday morning. After Romney said last Friday that the president’s proposals to put more teachers, firefighters and policemen back to work was a bad idea, the Obama campaign countered in the last few days that Romney would cut these jobs. “That’s a very strange accusation,” Romney said. “Of course, teachers and firemen and policemen are hired at the local level and also by states. The federal government doesn’t pay for teachers, firefighters or policemen. So obviously that’s completely absurd.” But Romney also stood by his opposition to the federal government facilitating more hiring public sector hiring. “He’s got a new idea, though, and that is to have another stimulus and to have the federal government send money to try and bail out cities and states,” Romney said of President Obama. “It didn’t work the first time. It certainly wouldn’t work the second time.”Hey – I understand that Fox & Friends prides itself on absolute stupidity but Mr. Romney aspires to be President. So we should expect a more intelligent discussion. During economic downturns, state and local governments face declining tax revenues and would be forced by their balanced budget constraints to cut spending even though such public austerity is destabilizing from a macroeconomic perspective. This is entire rationale for Federal revenue sharing, which is something that Republican Party has chosen to not only oppose but also to block in the Senate via the filibuster process. Is it working well now? Of course not - because we are not even trying to make it work thanks to this Republican opposition. When Mr. Romney protests in this fashion, he is exhibiting either stupidity of mendacity (to coin Brad DeLong’s phase). If he is really this stupid – he does not deserve to be our next President. But something tells me he is brighter than this – which means he is once again engaging in an incredibly dishonest campaign. But in case Mr. Romney is indeed this clueless, might I recommend something Robert Shiller wrote back in 2010?
Monday, June 11, 2012
Gramm-Hubbard: So Many Misconceptions, So Little Time
Glenn Hubbard appears to be getting drunk on GOP Kool-Aid again with an assist from Phil Gramm. As they try to argue that Mitt Romney will be the saving grace for our economy, they also contrast the current recession/recovery with what happened in the early 1980’s making so many ridiculous arguments, it is hard to keep track. But let’s start with their explanation for the most recent recession:
The more recent recession resulted from excessive government intervention to increase homeownership by expanding subprime housing loans, on which substantial leverage was built. The resulting wave of defaults damaged the base of the banking system.Two points here. The first is that Glenn served as economic advisor to that President who kept bragging about rising home ownership. Secondly, the problem was more too little government regulation of the banking system – not excessive regulation. But that line of reasoning is not nearly as bizarre as the following:
The superior job creation and income growth following the 1981-82 recession are all the more striking as they occurred against the backdrop of restrictive monetary policy … By reducing domestic discretionary spending, setting out a three-year program to reduce tax rates, and alleviating the regulatory burden, Reagan sought to make it profitable to invest in America again. He clearly succeeded. President Obama's polices would, by contrast, make permanent a significant surge in federal spending and raise marginal tax rates on earnings and entrepreneurial returns.Paul Krugman partially addresses my problem with this aspect of Gramm-Hubbard:
Because recessions like those of 1990-91, 2001, and 2007-2009 have very different origins from recessions like 1974-75 or the double-dip recession of 1979-82. The old recessions were more or less deliberately created by the Fed via tight money to control inflation, which meant that you had a V-shaped recovery once the Fed decided that we had suffered enough and loosened the reins.Gramm-Hubbard admitted earlier that it was Volcker’s tight monetary policies that lead to the double-dip recession of 1979-82. One would think these two economists understand our macroeconomic history enough to realize the Volcker reversed his monetary restraint. One would also hope that they understood – as most economists do – that Reagan’s fiscal stimulus wasn’t necessary and ended up leading to less investment not more. Paul’s point is that under the current liquidity trap situation, we need fiscal stimulus to restore full employment. Gramm-Hubbard also paint current U.S. fiscal policy as being very expansionary, which is not even remotely true. They also play the card that our current woes could be cured by less regulation. President Reagan did preside over the deregulation of the banking sector but note early in the Gramm-Hubbard op-ed their recognition of the savings-and-loan crisis. They blame the Volcker FED for this crisis but most economists blame what John Kareken dubbed putting the cart before the horse. Luigi Zingales appears to now support Glass-Steagall because of concerns similar to those that Kareken had with the financial deregulation during the early 1980’s. Somehow – all of this seems to have been missed by Phil Gramm and Glenn Hubbard.
Sunday, June 10, 2012
Does Mitt Romney Believe Downsizing Public Education is Good for Growth?
Pema Levy reports on what appears to be a real difference of opinion between President Obama and Mitt Romney (unless Romney flip flops on this issue too). First up this quote from Romney:
He wants another stimulus, he wants to hire more government workers. He says we need more firemen, more policemen, more teachers. Did he not get the message of Wisconsin? The American people did. It’s time for us to cut back on government and help the American people.It has been widely reported that the fiscal contraction by our state and local governments is holding back our feeble recovery from the Great Recession. And yet the Republican Party is calling for even more austerity. I guess they are taking their cues from those European austerians. How well is that working out? Both parties agree in principle that we need to improve our education system as part of a strategy for long-term growth. But this is where Team Romney seems to have extremely bizarre reasoning:
The ex-governor has said smaller class sizes don’t necessarily improve education. On Sunday, now-surrogate Rick Santorum defended Romney’s opposition to hiring more teachers. “Teachers are great, we love teachers,” Santorum said on ABC’s “This Week.” “But if anybody believes that hiring more teachers as we did over the many, many years in this country, under President Clinton, even President Bush and under the early part of President Obama’s administration, if that’s dramatically improved the quality of education, you got to show me the numbers because it’s not. … What we need to do is have education reform, not throw more money at teachers. And Mitt Romney understands that.”Less spending on education and fewer teachers does not strike me as a recipe for improving education. But this has become a theme among Republicans of late. Update: The Romney Camp is saying President Obama is bragging about those reductions in government employment even though the facts are that the President has made proposals to reverse this trend with Congressional Republicans blocking these proposals. Not quite a blatant flip-flop but Romney’s dishonesty is certainly designed to muddy this issue.
Friday, June 8, 2012
Michael Gerson Messes Up On Wisconsin Election Analysis
In the Washington Post today, tendentious moralist Michael Gerson opines that labor unions are driving a wedge into the Democratic Party. He bases this on the Wisconsin recall election, where Governor Walker trounced Milwaukee Mayor Tom Barrett. He argues that this was all about public sector unions getting too much money into their pension funds and wages, which in a recessionary period conflicts with various progressive spending agendas. He points to local Dem mayors such as Reed in San Jose, CA, who have pushed for reductions in pensions for local public workers against union wishes and won strongly in referenda supporting their efforts, to excoriate Barrett and call for dismantling collective bargaining for public sector unions.
Now, whatever one thinks of public sector unions, Gerson's account is seriously misleading and lacking in facts on several fronts. First is that while Barrett certainly became associated with the position of the public sector unions in the final race, as mayor he had done exactly as Reed in San Jose and had angered the public sector unions in Milwaukee for doing so. They had supported his main rival in the primary, Kathleen Falk of liberal Dane County over him, with this intra-party fight being pointed to by many as one of the reasons for Barrett's loss, along with the blunder of holding the recall election in the summer after students had all gone home, who are more inclined to support the Dems than the GOP. This is on top of Gerson's conveniently ignoring that many of those voting for Walker apparently did so out of simply disapproving of holding the recall election at all.
The other issue is that he completely ignores the fact that the public sector unions in Wisconsin had completely agreed to virtually all of Walker's financial demands regarding pay and pensions and so on. This was not about the deficit or other financial matters. It was all about public sector union-busting, which in fact Gerson does support. But part of what got so many people angry was that Walker never said anything about this when he was running. He certainly spoke about limiting public worker pensions and so on, but never whispered a hint about his plan to severely limit collective bargaining.
What is curious is that on the same page, the generally obnoxious Charles Krauthammer got most of this right, although Krauthammer was probably even more gloating and mocking than Gerson regarding the impact of all this on the union movement, which does look pretty severe.
Now, whatever one thinks of public sector unions, Gerson's account is seriously misleading and lacking in facts on several fronts. First is that while Barrett certainly became associated with the position of the public sector unions in the final race, as mayor he had done exactly as Reed in San Jose and had angered the public sector unions in Milwaukee for doing so. They had supported his main rival in the primary, Kathleen Falk of liberal Dane County over him, with this intra-party fight being pointed to by many as one of the reasons for Barrett's loss, along with the blunder of holding the recall election in the summer after students had all gone home, who are more inclined to support the Dems than the GOP. This is on top of Gerson's conveniently ignoring that many of those voting for Walker apparently did so out of simply disapproving of holding the recall election at all.
The other issue is that he completely ignores the fact that the public sector unions in Wisconsin had completely agreed to virtually all of Walker's financial demands regarding pay and pensions and so on. This was not about the deficit or other financial matters. It was all about public sector union-busting, which in fact Gerson does support. But part of what got so many people angry was that Walker never said anything about this when he was running. He certainly spoke about limiting public worker pensions and so on, but never whispered a hint about his plan to severely limit collective bargaining.
What is curious is that on the same page, the generally obnoxious Charles Krauthammer got most of this right, although Krauthammer was probably even more gloating and mocking than Gerson regarding the impact of all this on the union movement, which does look pretty severe.
Subscribe to:
Posts (Atom)