http://www.huffingtonpost.com/ca-rotwang/mr-president-tweak-this_b_1954374.html?utm_hp_ref=politics
Read it and weep.
Read it and weep.
In August, the labor-force participation rate in the U.S. dropped to 63.5%, the lowest since September 1981. By definition, fewer people in the workforce leads to better unemployment numbers. That's why the unemployment rate dropped to 8.1% in August from 8.3% in July. Meanwhile, we're told in the BLS report that in the months of August and September, federal, state and local governments added 602,000 workers to their payrolls, the largest two-month increase in more than 20 years.The first claim is true – the labor force participation rate did fall from 63.7% to 63.5% but Welch conveniently omits the fact that this same rate rose from 63.5% to 63.6% as of September. And who told Mr. Welch that reported government employment shot up by over 600 thousand workers in just two months? I guess this person may have been Neil Cavuto or perhaps Donald Luskin because when I checked out the same series per FRED, I see an increase of only 55,000 over the past 3 months. As our graph shows, we have seen a very mild reversal of the unfortunate downward drift of government employment (I'm using seasonally adjusted data here - Mr. Welch didn't say what he was using and his claim is not even consistent with the data not seasonally adjusted). In all of his rants, Mr. Welch has proven only one thing – he is utterly clueless per the employment statistics that the professionals at the Bureau of Labor Statistics report. Before he decides to attack their integrity again – might I suggest he actually learn something about what they report?
I don’t make up numbers ... you have lied about every position and every particular of the Ryan plan on Medicare from the efficiency of Medicare administration to calling it a voucher plan ... You are hardly credible on calling somebody else a liar.Actually - it was established a long time ago that Mary Matalin is a partisan hack but what about this claim:
Has there ever been this not be true in history that the deeper — the deeper the recession, the steeper and stronger the recovery. There is no such thing as a deep recession with a moderate recovery.Poor Mary had not read this:
Fact-checking financial recessions is a salient issue, especially in a US election year. On the one hand, the incumbent faces criticism that the recovery is slow. In August the Mitt Romney campaign invoked US history to argue that performance has been poor: “The 2007-2009 financial crisis produced a severe recession ... But GDP growth has been anaemic since then, averaging just 2.2% per year since the trough. This pattern is unusual. The past ten recessions have been followed by faster recoveries, and GDP has fairly swiftly recovered to the previous trendline.” On the other hand, none of the last ten US downturns coincided with a financial crisis. In his convention speech nominating Barack Obama a month later, Bill Clinton intimated that the usual pattern in normal recessions was not relevant in this instance: “The difference this time is purely in the circumstances… no president, not me, not any of my predecessors, no one could have fully repaired all the damage that he found in just four years.” ... We reach back into the historical record over 140 years, examining the experiences of 14 advanced countries, to document the pervasive cyclical influence of credit in the economic fortunes of nations … The more excess credit in the preceding expansion, the worse the recession and subsequent recovery appear to be ... By this reckoning the US has done quite well, steering out of the to-be-expected financial recession range based on the inherited level of excess credit, especially if the shadow system is considered. Most importantly a deep financial recession was avoided at the outset, and this level effect remained intact ... To assume that this US recovery would resemble previous “normal recession” is to use the wrong benchmark.There is a very simple way to think about this using standard IS-LM thinking. The 10 recessions from the late 1940’s to 2001 (see this for the dating of US business cycles) differed from the Great Recession as well as the Great Depression in terms of the ability of conventional monetary policy to quickly reverse these milder recessions. In those 10 situations, we could have and actually did reverse these recessions by allowing interest rates to fall. Some of these recessions (notably the ones from 1969 to 1982) were started by deliberate monetary contractions to “Whip Inflation Now” as President Ford once quipped. The ability to rely on monetary expansion had lead many economists including myself to wonder if we ever really needed fiscal stimulus to manage downturns in the modern business cycle. Yes – more fiscal stimulus would have been called for during the Great Depression but not in the modern US economy – unless we fell victim once again to the liquidity trap. The financial crisis in other nations such as Japan should have warned us that falling into a liquidity trap was a real possibility but I guess we had to relearn the lessons of history on our own. When Barack Obama prevailed in November 2008, he seemed to realize the need for a massive and effective stimulus package but alas didn’t push hard enough for what Christina Romer recommended. And alas, US fiscal policy has recently drifted towards austerity. So while I agree with those who argue that policy responses to severe financial crisis are different than policy responses to garden variety recessions, all this really means is that we may have to look beyond conventional monetary policies to have quick and effective remedies to downturns in aggregate demand. Alas the Republican Party and Team Romney to date has been opposed to fiscal stimulus unless it is of the military Keynesian brand.
“I don’t want to go down the path of Spain,” Romney said Wednesday night during the first presidential debate. He argued that government spending under Obama has reached 42 percent of the U.S. economy, a figure comparable with America’s NATO ally. “I want to go down the path of growth that puts Americans to work.” … No one contests that Spain’s situation is dire, its economy in deep recession and unemployment hovering around 25 percent. But Spain’s level of government spending is actually low by European standards, and significantly less than Germany and Scandinavian countries with far healthier economic prospects. Spain’s woes were chiefly caused by the collapse of a property bubble that had fueled more than a decade of booming economic growth.Klapper is properly noting that the U.S. recession and the Spanish recession were both caused by similar private sector events. The U.S. has fared less badly than some countries because we at least tried a bit of fiscal stimulus for a little while. Romney has been confused whether we should follow the UK’s disastrous austerity or use military Keynesianism. As far as Spain Matt Yglesias provides a nice graph showing how fast the changed in nominal government spending in Spain has declined:
If the entire argument is really over whether or not this Noteworthy Mercatusward Change in Spanish fiscal policy deserves to be called "cuts" rather than "rapid deceleration" then I suppose we've all wasted our time.This may not have been the headline lie among all of Romney’s lies during the debate. And maybe Romney was less being dishonest than just completely ignorant of the facts in Spain. But it is very evident that he is either completely ignorant of the macroeconomic situation in the U.S. or is being incredibly dishonest. But hey – what else is news?
In January 1999, a trust set up by Mitt Romney for his children and grandchildren reaped a 1,000 percent return on the sale of shares in Internet advertising firm DoubleClick Inc. If Romney had given the cash directly, he could have owed a gift tax at a rate as high as 55 percent … Romney or his trust received shares in DoubleClick eight months before the company went public in 1998. The trust sold them less than a year after the IPO … In January 1999, Romney’s trust sold $746,000 worth of DoubleClick shares, for a gain of about $674,000, or an almost 1,000 percent returnVia Brad DeLong we see that Daniel Shaviro claimed:
The extreme undervaluation certainly looks like tax fraud. Key evidence would be the close proximity of the valuation date and the sale dateWhat was the fair market value of this DoubleClick stock when Romney set up this trust fund? Drucker and Shaviro are certainly arguing that the fair market value was much higher than what was claimed at the time these shares were gifted. We should note, however, that the value of Doubleclick shares has had a controversial history even up to the time that Google purchased the company for over $3 billion during April 2007. About two years earlier, a private equity firm had purchased the company for just over $1 billion:
DoubleClick shareholders will get $8.50 in cash for every common stock share, a 10.6 per cent premium over the average closing price of the company's stock in the last thirty trading days. The valuation is very low compared to DoubleClick's valuation in its hey days.We should also note that two people commented over at Brad’s place that stock valuations were quite volatile if not exuberant during the late 1990’s. Mind you that I’d be the last to cast doubt on this Drucker-Shaviro claim that Mitt Romney hired some hack appraiser:
But back to the estate attorney who has a Rolodex of appraisers who will give him any whore answer for the right fee. The appraiser/whore that is chosen to evaluate the fair market value of the business has three tricks up his (her) sleeve ... Doesn’t the IRS have their own appraisers that can effectively rebut the bogus valuation reports commissioned by the estate attorney? One would think so – but read most of the Tax Court decisions in this area and realize that even the National Review looks smart and honest by comparison.Shaviro’s “Key evidence would be the close proximity of the valuation date and the sale date” reminds me of the “expert” testimony in Nestle v. Commissioner of the Internal Revenue Service which involved the value of the various Carnation trademarks and other intangible assets both at the time the U.S. affiliate of Nestle purchased Carnation (January 1985) and when this affiliate sold them to the Swiss parent, which was on April 30, 1985. Nestle had commissioned one appraiser to argue that the value of the intangible assets was approximately $425 million at both dates. The IRS, however, argued that the value of the intangible assets was only $175 million as of January 1985 but accepted the $425 million value for the intercompany sale price as of April 30, 1985. I’m sure if one wished to read the trial court decision which accepted the IRS view one could mock at the quality of analysis by both sides, and the Appeal Court ultimately rejected the IRS position for its own silly reasons. But note that the IRS never bothered to explain why the intangible assets in such a mundane industry could more than double in a period of less than four months. Which is to simply say – both sides often play games when it comes to valuations for tax purposes.
Empirically, it's a bit difficult to verify that variations in capital gains tax rates and the like really are making a material difference to investment levels. But then again the data is noisy. What's more the thing we have the most real-world experience with is measures like George W. Bush 2003 tax cut for investment income which was financed with government borrowing rather than higher wage taxes, consumption taxes, or spending cuts. It's not at all clear that the basic theoretical considerations in favor of low taxes on investment income apply to the case of a debt-financed tax cut. This is also separate from the question of whether hedge fund and private equity fund managers should be allowed to pretend their labor income is really investment income by calling it "carried interest" and paying at a low rate.Indeed we had another experiment with lowering tax rates on capital income that actually increased real interest rates and lowered investment – that being the original Reagan “supply-side” tax cut. Of course, Team Romney keeps wanted to pretend they have found some magic recipe for deficit neutral ways of reducing taxation on capital income. The problem, however, as Howard Gleckman notes is that when Team Romney member Kevin Hassett was forced to defend the revenue neutral proposition he had to basically admit you cannot do that without abandoning the reduction in tax rates for the well to do. But I think there is another fatal flaw in Matt’s defense of lower tax rates on capital income. Let me start with Matt’s example:
You imagine two prosperous but not outrageously so working people living somewhere—two doctors, say, living in nearby small towns. They're both pulling in incomes in the low six figures.OK – now let’s give the microphone to Dean Baker who was discussing a similar argument by Dylan Matthews:
Matthews rests his case on some arguments in the literature concerning scenarios in which we both look to an infinite future horizon and we have identically situated individuals, meaning that we all have the same wealth and the same opportunity to gain income. When these assumptions are relaxed, the case for preferential treatment of capital income becomes considerably weaker, as argued in a recent Journal of Economic Perspectives article by Peter Diamond and Emmanuel Saez … If we have some individuals who inherit immense wealth so that they can live entirely off their capital income and other individuals who must work for their income, a policy that subjects capital income tax to a lower rate of taxation than labor income means that we are taxing the rich at a lower rate than the middle class and poor. It is difficult to see how this is either efficient (we are giving disincentives to work for middle class people as a result of a higher than necessary tax rate) or fair. Furthermore, as a result of having a lower tax rate on capital income than labor income we are giving people an incentive to game the tax code by concealing labor income as capital income. While most workers may not have much opportunity to play such games, higher end workers, such as doctors or lawyers with their own practices would have ample opportunities for such gaming. This is both unfair and leads to a waste of resources as these people employ accountants to rig their books.Team Romney can pretend all they want that we all have similar endowments of initial resources and that any change in the tax code will somehow magically be paid for by offsetting fiscal restraint, but actual policy decisions must be made in the real world where things are not nearly as magical.
By "Image of Limited Good" I mean that broad areas of peasant behavior are patterned in such fashion as to suggest that peasants view their social, economic, and natural universes -- their total environment -- as one in which all of the desired things in life such as land, wealth, health, friendship and love, manliness and honor, respect and status, power and influence, security and safety, exist in finite quantity and are always in short supply, as far as the peasant is concerned. Not only do these and all other "good things" exist in finite and limited quantities, but in addition there is no way directly within peasant power to increase the available quantities. It is as if the obvious fact of land shortage in a densely populated area applied to all other desired things: not enough to go around. "Good," like land, is seen as inherent in nature, there to be divided and redivided, if necessary, but not to be augmented.In short, Foster's paper adopts the lump-of-labor fallacy claim and extends it to non-economic spheres of life. Actually, I would rate Foster's explanation of his image of limited good as more scholarly than any explanation of the lump-of-labor fallacy I have encountered. It is more conscientiously qualified and observational data are presented as supporting evidence. Nevertheless, as Hinton's commentary suggested, the model has been controversial, to say the least. In a 1975 article offering an alternative explanation for Foster's field observations, James R. Gregory summarized the critical reaction to Foster's article to that date. I have previously posted Gregory's summary in "Trickster Makes This Lump". As I mentioned there, I can find absolutely no evidence of disciplinary 'cross-pollination' where economists recognize the image as their own fallacy claim or anthropologists note the fallacy claim as the image's progenitor.
This myth—that you can just give money to the middle class and good things happen—is widely shared and is at the basis of a lot of government policy. And it is why the recovery is stuck between lack and luster. Let's go back. Henry Ford is popularly credited with inventing the middle class by doubling his workers' salaries to $5 per day in 1914. A multiplier for the economy, right? Wrong. The year before, Ford revolutionized manufacturing with the moving assembly line, slashing automobile build times to just 90 minutes from 14 hours. That's productivity. It allowed Ford to reduce the price over time of his Model T to $290 from $950. Demand took off because it was far cheaper than the cars made by his 88 competitors.While I’ll grant that the Model T is not be an example of the Keynesian multiplier that most macroeconomist talk about. As far as explaining to Mr. Kessler how this economy is indeed suffering from a lack of demand - Martin Sullivan does the heavy lifting. So let me present Kessler’s other two examples of the i-Side multiplier:
Investor Peter Thiel put $500,000 into Facebook in August 2004, a company now worth $50 billion based on its prospects for transforming the media industry. What multiplier would you put on his investment? This month, after investing billions over the years on R&D, Apple released the iPhone 5. The company is worth $666 billion based on prospects that hundreds of millions of users will lower their cost of doing business with the latest iPhone and iPad mini and whatever else is coming. What is that multiplier?Kessler is a hedge fund manager. Does he really think every R&D project has incredibly high returns? There are no losers? I would think a hedge fund manager would understate the need to present the expected return to R&D which most research in financial economics shows barely covers the additional systematic risk that investors undertake. If Mr. Kessler does not understand this – I have a suggestion for how you can get rich. Figure out which stocks Kessler is buying and then sell them short.